American Economic Association Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda Author(s): Ross Levine Source: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 2 (Jun., 1997), pp. 688-726 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2729790 . Accessed: 15/09/2013 08:53 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Economic Literature. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XXXV (June 1997), pp. 688-726 Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda Ross LEVINE Universityof Virginia I thank, without implicating, GerardCaprio, Maria Carkovic,David Cole, Robert Cull, William Easterly, Mark Gertler, Fabio Schiantarelli, Mary Shirley, Bruce Smith, and Kenneth Sokolofffor criticisms, guidance, and encouragement.This paper was written while I was at the WorldBank. Opinionsexpressedare those of the author and do not necessarilyreflectthe views of the WorldBank,its staff, or membercountries. Doesfinance make a difference . . .? RaymondGoldsmith(1969, p. 408) I. Introduction:Goals and Boundaries ECONOMISTS HOLD startlingly different opinions regarding the importance of the financial system for economic growth. Walter Bagehot (1873) and John Hicks (1969) argue that it played a critical role in igniting industrialization in England by facilitating the mobilization of capital for "immense works." Joseph Schumpeter (1912) contends that well-functioning banks spur technological innovation by identifying and funding those entrepreneurs with the best chances of successfully implementing innovative products and production processes. In contrast, JoanRobinson (1952, p. 86) declares that "where enterprise leads finance follows." According to this view, economic development creates demands for particular types of financial arrangements, and the financial system responds automatically to these demands. Moreover, some economists just do not believe that the finance-growth relationship is important. Robert Lucas (1988, p. 6) asserts that economists "badly over-stress" the role of financial factors in economic growth, while development economists frequently express their skepticism about the role of the financial system by ignoring it (Anand Chandavarkar1992). For example, a collection of essays by the "pioneers of development economics," including three Nobel Laureates, does not mention finance (Gerald Meir and Dudley Seers 1984). Furthermore, Nicholas Stern's (1989) review of development economics does not discuss the financial system, even in a section that lists omitted topics. In light of these conflicting views, this paper uses existing theory to organize an analytical framework of the finance-growth nexus and then assesses the quantitative importance of the financial system in economic growth. Although conclusions must be stated hesitantly and with ample qualifications, the preponderance of theoretical reasoning and empirical evidence suggests a positive, first-order relationship between financial development and economic growth. A growing body of work would push even most skeptics toward the be- 688 This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 689 lief that the development of financial markets and institutions is a critical and inextricable part of the growth process and awayfrom the view that the financial system is an inconsequential side show, responding passively to economic growth and industrialization. There is even evidence that the level of financial development is a good predictor of future rates of economic growth, capital accumulation, and technological change. Moreover, cross country, case study, industry- and firm-level analyses document extensive periods when financial development-or the lack thereof-crucially affects the speed and pattern of economic development. To arrive at these conclusions and to highlight areas in acute need of additional research, I organize the remainder of this paper as follows. Section II explains what the financial system does and how it affects-and is affected by-economic growth. Theory suggests that financial instruments, markets, and institutions arise to mitigate the effects of information and transaction costs.1 Furthermore, a growing literature shows that differences in how well financial systems reduce information and transaction costs influence saving rates, investment decisions, technological innovation, and long-run growth rates. Also, a comparativelyless developed theoretical literature demonstrates how changes in economic activity can influence financial systems. Section II also advocates the functional approach to understanding the role of financial systems in economic growth. This approach focuses on the ties between growth and the quality of the functions provided by the financial system. These functions include facilitating the trading of risk, allocating capital, monitoring managers, mobilizing savings, and easing the trading of goods, services, and financial contracts.2 The basic functions remain constant through time and across countries. There are large differences across countries and time, however, in the quality of financial services and in the types of financial instruments, markets, and institutions that arise to provide these services. While focusing on functions, this approach does not diminish the role of institutions. Indeed, the functional approach highlights the importance of examining an underresearched topic: the relationship between financial structure-the mix of financial instruments, markets, and institutions-and the provision of financial services. Thus, this approachdiscourages a narrow focus on one financial instrument, like money, or a particularinstitution, like banks. Instead, the functional approach prompts a more comprehensive-and more difficult-question: what is the relationship between financial structure and the functioning of the financial system?3 Part III then turns to the evidence. While many gaps remain, broad crosscountry comparisons, individual country studies, industry-level analyses, and firm-level investigations point in the 1 These frictions include the costs of acquiring information, enforcing contracts, and exchanging goods and financialclaims. 2 For different ways of categorizing financial functions, see Cole and Betty Slade (1991) and Robert C. Merton and Zvi Bodie (1995). 3 The majoralternativeapproachto studying finance and economic growth is based on the seminal contributions of John Gurley and Edward Shaw (1955), James Tobin (1965), and Ronald McKinnon (1973). In their mathematical models, as distinct from their narratives, they focus on money. This narrowfocus can restrict the analysis of the finance-growth nexus, and lead to a misleading distinction between the "real"and financial sectors. In contrast, the functional approach highlights the value added of the financial sector. The financial system is a "real" sector: it researches firms and managers, exerts corporate control, and facilitates risk management, exchange, and resource mobilization. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 690 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) same direction: the functioning of financial systems is vitally linked to economic growth. Specifically, countries with larger banks and more active stock markets grow faster over subsequent decades even after controlling for many other factors underlying economic growth. Industries and firms that rely heavily on external financing grow disproportionately faster in countries with well-developed banks and securities markets than in countries with poorly developed financial systems. Moreover, ample country studies suggest that differences in financial development have, in some countries over extensive periods, critically influenced economic development. Yet, these results do not imply that finance is everywhere and alwaysexogenous to economic growth. Economic activity and technological innovation undoubtedly affect the structure and quality of financial systems. Innovations in telecommunications and computing have undeniably affected the financial services industry. Moreover, "thirdfactors," such as a country's legal system and political institutions certainly drive both financial and economic development at critical junctures during the growth process. Nevertheless, the weight of evidence suggests that financial systems are a fundamental feature of the process of economic development and that a satisfactory understanding of the factors underlying economic growth requires a greater understanding of the evolution and structure of financial systems. As in any critique, I omit or treat cursorily important issues. Here I highlight two.4 First, I do not discuss the relationship between international finance and growth. This paper narrows its conceptual focus by studying the financial services available to an economy regardless of the geographic source of those services. In measuring financial development, however, researchers often do not account sufficiently for international trade in financial services. Second, the paper does not discuss policy. Given the links between the functioning of the financial system and economic growth, designing optimal financial sector policies is critically important. A rigorous discussion of these policies, however, would require a long article or book by itself.5 Instead, this paper seeks to pull together a diverse and active literature into a coherent view of the financial system in economic growth. II. TheFunctions of the Financial System A. Functional Approach:Introduction The costs of acquiringinformation and making transactions create incentives for the emergence of financial markets and institutions. Put differently, in a Kenneth Arrow (1964)-Gerard Debreu (1959) state-contingent claim framework with no information or transaction costs, there is no need for a financial system that expends resources researching projects, scrutinizing managers, or designing arrangements to ease risk management and facilitate transactions.Thus, anytheory of the role of the financial system in economic growth (implicitly or explicitly) adds specific frictions to the ArrowDebreu model. Financial markets and institutions may arise to ameliorate the problems created by information and transactions frictions. Different types and combinations of information and transaction costs motivate distinct financial contracts, markets,and institutions. 4Also, the theoretical review focuses on purely real economies and essentially ignores work on finance and growthin monetaryeconomies. 5 The financialpolicy literatureis immense. See, for example, Philip Brock (1992), Alberto Giovannini and MarthaDe Melo (1993), Caprio,IsakAtiyas, and James Hanson (1994), and Maxwell Fry (1995). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 691 In arising to ameliorate transaction and information costs, financial systems serve one primary function: they facilitate the allocation of resources, across space and time, in an uncertain environment (Merton and Bodie 1995, p. 12). To organize the vast literature on finance and economic activity, I break this primary function into five basic func- tions. Specifically, financial systems - facilitate the trading, hedging, diversifying, and pooling of risk, - allocate resources, - monitor managers and exert corporate control, - mobililize savings, and - facilitate the exchange of goods and services. This section explains how particular market frictions motivate the emergence of financial markets and intermediaries that provide these five functions, and explains how they affect economic growth. I examine two channels through which each financial function may affect economic growth: capital accumulation and technological innovation. On capital accumulation, one class of growth models uses either capital externalities or capital goods produced using constant returns to scale but without the use of nonreproducible factors to generate steady-state per capita growth (Paul Romer 1986; Lucas 1988; Sergio Rebelo 1991). In these models, the functions performed by the financial system affect steady-state growth by influencing the rate of capital formation. The financial system affects capital accumulation either by altering the savings rate or by reallocating savings among different capital producing technologies. On technological innovation, a second class of growth models focuses on the invention of new production processes and goods (Romer 1990; Gene Grossman and Elhanan Helpman 1991; and Philippe Marketfrictions - informationcosts - transactioncosts Financialmarkets and intermediaries Financialfunctions - mobilize savings - allocateresources - exertcorporatecontrol - facilitateriskmanagement - ease tradingof goods, services,contracts Channelsto growth - capitalaccumulation - technologicalinnovation Growth Figure 1. A Theoretical Approach to Finance and Growth Aghion and Peter Howitt 1992). In these models, the functions performed by the financial system affect steady-state growth by altering the rate of technological innovation. Thus, as sketched in Figure 1, the remainder of this section discusses how specific market frictions motivate the emergence of financial contracts, markets, and intermediaries and how these financial arrangements provide five financial functions that affect saving and allocations decisions in ways that influence economic growth. B. Facilitating RiskAmelioration In the presence of specific information and transaction costs, financial markets and institutions may arise to ease the trading, hedging, and pooling of risk. This subsection considers two types of risk: liquidity and idiosyncratic risk. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 692 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Liquidity is the ease and speed with which agents can convert assets into purchasing power at agreed prices. Thus, real estate is typically less liquid than equities, and equities in the United States are typically more liquid than those traded on the Nigerian Stock Exchange. Liquidity risk arises due to the uncertainties associated with converting assets into a medium of exchange. Informational asymmetries and transaction costs may inhibit liquidity and intensify liquidity risk. These frictions create incentives for the emergence of financial markets and institutions that augment liquidity. Liquid capital markets, therefore, are markets where it is relatively inexpensive to trade financial instruments and where there is little uncertainty about the timing and settlement of those trades. Before delving into formal models of liquidity and economic activity, some intuition and history may help motivate the discussion. The link between liquidity and economic development arises because some high-return projects require a long-run commitment of capital, but savers do not like to relinquish control of their savings for long periods. Thus, if the financial system does not augment the liquidity of long-term investments, less investment is likely to occur in the high-return projects. Indeed, Sir John Hicks (1969, pp. 143-45) argues that the capital market improvements that mitigated liquidity risk were primarycauses of the industrial revolution in England. According to Hicks, the products manufactured during the first decades of the industrial revolution had been invented much earlier. Thus, technological innovation did not, spark sustained growth. Many of these existing inventions, however, required large injections and longrun commitments of capital. The critical new ingredient that ignited growth in eighteenth century England was capital marketliquidity. With liquid capital markets, savers can hold assets-like equity, bonds, or demand deposits-that they can sell quickly and easily if they seek access to their savings. Simultaneously, capital marketstransformthese liquid financial instruments into long-term capital investments in illiquid production processes. Because the industrial revolution required large commitments of capital for long periods, the industrial revolution may not have occurred without this liquidity transformation."Theindustrial revolution therefore had to wait for the financial revolution" (Valerie Bencivenga, Bruce Smith, and Ross Starr 1966, p. 243).6 Economists have recently modeled the emergence of financial markets in response to liquidity risk and examined how these financial markets affect economic growth. For example, in Douglas Diamond and Philip Dybvig's (1983) seminal model of liquidity, a fraction of savers receive shocks after choosing between two investments: an illiquid, highreturn project and a liquid, low-return project. Those receiving shocks want access to their savings before the illiquid project produces. This risk creates incentives for investing in the liquid, lowreturn projects. The model assumes that it is prohibitively costly to verify whether another individual has received a shock or not. This information cost assumption rules out state-contingent insurance contracts and creates an incentive for financial markets-markets where individuals issue and trade securities-to emerge. In Levine (1991), savers receiving shocks 6 The financial revolution included the emergence of joint-stock companies with nonredeemable capital. The Dutch East India Company made capital permanent in 1609, and Cromwell made the Engfish East India Companycapitalpermanent in 1650. These financial innovations formed the basis of liquid equity markets (Larry Neal 1990). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 693 can sell their equity claims on the profits of the illiquid production technology to others. Marketparticipants do not verify whether other agents received shocks or not; participants simply trade in impersonal stock exchanges. Thus, with liquid stock markets, equity holders can readily sell their shares, while firms have permanent access to the capital invested by the initial shareholders. By facilitating trade, stock markets reduce liquidity risk.7 As stock market transaction costs fall, more investment occurs in the illiquid, highreturn project. If illiquid projects enjoy sufficiently large externalities, then greater stock market liquidity induces faster steady-state growth. Thus far, information costs-the costs of verifying whether savers have received a shock-have motivated the existence of stock markets. Trading costs can also highlight the role of liquidity. For example, different production technologies may have a wide arrayof gestation periods for converting current output into future capital, where longer-run technologies enjoy greater returns. Investors, however, may be reluctant to relinquish control of their savings for very long periods. Thus, long-gestation production technologies require that ownership be transferred throughout the life of the production process in secondary securities markets(Bencivenga, B. Smith, and Starr 1995). If exchanging ownership claims is costly, then longer-run production technologies will be less attractive. Thus, liquidity-as measured by secondary market trading costs-affects production decisions. Greater liquidity will induce a shift to longer-gestation, higher-return technologies. Besides stock markets, financial intermediaries-coalitions of agents that combine to provide financial services-may also enhance liquidity and reduce liquidity risk. As discussed above, Diamond and Dybvig's (1983) model assumes it is prohibitively costly to observe shocks to individuals, so it is impossible to write incentive compatible state-contingent insurance contracts. Under these conditions, banks can offer liquid deposits to savers and undertake a mixture of liquid, low-return investments to satisfy demands on deposits and illiquid, high-return investments. By providing demand deposits and choosing an appropriatemixture of liquid and illiquid investments, banksprovide complete insurance to savers against liquidity risk while simultaneously facilitating long-run investments in high-return projects. Banks replicate the equilibrium allocation of capital that exists with observable shocks. By eliminating liquidity risk, banks can increase investment in the high-return, illiquid asset and accelerate growth (Bencivenga and B. Smith 1991). There is a problem, however, with this description of the role of banks as reducing liquidity risk. The banking equilibrium is not incentive compatible if agents can trade in liquid equity markets; if equity markets exist, all agents will use equities; none will use banks (Charles Jacklin 1987). Thus, in this context, banks will only emerge to provide liquidity if there are sufficiently large impediments to trading in securities markets (Gary Gorton and George Pennacchi 1990).8 7 Frictionless stock markets, however, do not eliminate liquidity risk. That is, stock markets do not replicate the equilibrium that exists when insurance contracts can be written contingent on observingwhether an agent receives a shock or not. 8 Goldsmith (1969, p. 396) notes that "Claims againstfinancialinstitutions are generally easier to liquidate (i.e., to turn into cash without or with only insignificant delay, formality, and cost) than are primary debt securities. They have the additional great advantage of being completely divisible, whereas primarysecurities are usually issued in fixed amounts and often in amounts that make them very inconvenient for purchase and sale when lenders have small resources and when numerous individual purchase and sale transactions are involved." This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 694 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Theory, however, suggests that enhanced liquidity has an ambiguous affect on savingrates and economic growth.9In most models, greater liquidity (a) increases investment returns and (b) lowers uncertainty. Higher returns ambiguously affect saving rates due to wellknown income and substitution effects. Further, lower uncertainty ambiguously affects savings rates (David Levhari and T. N. Srinivasan 1969). Thus, saving rates may rise or fall as liquidity rises. Indeed, in a model with physical capital externalities, saving rates could fall enough, so that growth actually decelerates with greater liquidity (Tullio Jappelli and MarcoPagano 1994).10 Besides reducing liquidity risk, financial systems may also mitigate the risks associated with individual projects, firms, industries, regions, countries, etc. Banks, mutual funds, and securities markets all provide vehicles for trading, pooling, and diversifying risk.1"The financial system's abilityto provide risk diversification services can affect long-run economic growth by altering resource allocation and the saving rates. The basic intuition is straightforward.While savers generally do not like risk, high-return projects tend to be riskier than low-return projects. Thus, financial markets that ease risk diversification tend to induce a portfolio shift toward projects with higher expected returns (Gilles Saint-Paul 1992; Michael Devereux and Gregor Smith 1994; and Maurice Obstfeld 1994). Greater risk sharing and more efficient capital allocation, however, have theoretically ambiguous effects on saving rates as noted above. The savings rate could fall enough so that, when coupled with an externality-based or linear growth model, overall economic growth falls. With externalities, growth could fall sufficiently so that overall welfare falls with greater risk diversifica- tion. Besides the link between risk diversification and capital accumulation, risk diversification can also affect technological change. Agents are continuously trying to make technological advances to gain a profitable marketniche. Besides yielding profits to the innovator, successful innovation accelerates technological change. Engaging in innovation is risky,however. The ability to hold a diversified portfolio of innovative projects reduces risk and promotes investment in growth-enhancing innovative activities (with sufficiently risk averse agents). Thus, financial systems that ease risk diversification can accelerate technological change and economic growth (Robert King and Levine 1993c). C. Acquiring Information About Investments and Allocating Resources It is difficult and costly to evaluate firms, managers, and market conditions as discussed by Vincent Carosso (1970). Individual savers may not have the time, capacity, or means to collect and process information on a wide array of enterprises, managers, and economic conditions. Saverswill be reluctant to invest in activities about which there is little reli- 9The analyses described thus far focus on the links between liquidity and capital accumulation. Yet, liquidity may also affect the rate of technological change if long-run commitments of resources to research and development promote technological innovation. 10Similarly, although greater liquidity unambiguously raises the real return on savings, more liquidity may induce a reallocation of investment out of initiating new capital investments and into purchasing claims on ongoing projects. This may lower the rate of real investment enough to dece1erate growth (Bencivenga, B. Smith, and Starr 1995). 11Although the recent uses of options and futures contractsto hedge riskhave been well publicized, the development of these financial contracts is by no means recent. Josef Penso de la Vega published a treatise on options contracts, futures contracts, and securities marketspeculation, Confusion de Confusiones, in 1688! This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 695 able information. Consequently, high information costs may keep capital from flowing to its highest value use. Information acquisition costs create incentives for financial intermediaries to emerge (Diamond 1984; and John Boyd and Edward Prescott 1986). Assume, for example, that there is a fixed cost to acquiring information about a production technology. Without intermediaries, each investor must pay the fixed cost. In response to this information cost structure, however, groups of individuals may form (or join or use) financial intermediaries to economize on the costs of acquiring and processing information about investments. Instead of each individual acquiring evaluation skills and then conducting evaluations, an intermediary can do it for all its members. Economizing on information acquisition costs facilitates the acquisition of information about investment opportunities and thereby improves resource alloca- tion. The ability to acquire and process information may have important growth implications. Because many firms and entrepreneurs will solicit capital, financial intermediaries, and markets that are better at selecting the most promising firms and managers will induce a more efficient allocation of capital and faster growth (Jeremy Greenwood and Boyan Jovanovic 1990). Bagehot (1873, p. 53) expressed this view over 120 years ago. [England'sfinancial]organizationis so useful because it is so easily adjusted. Political economistssay that capitalsets towardsthe most profitabletrades, and that it rapidly leaves the less profitablenon-payingtrades. But in ordinarycountriesthis is a slowprocess, . . . In England,however,. . . capital runsas surelyandinstantlywhereit is most wanted,andwherethereis mostto be made ofit, aswaterrunsto findits level. England's financial system did a better job at identifying and funding profitable ventures than most countries in the mid- 1800s, which helped it enjoy comparatively greater economic success.12 Besides identifying the best production technologies, financial intermediaries may also boost the rate of technological innovation by identifying those entrepreneurs with the best chances of successfully initiating new goods and production processes (King and Levine 1993c). As eloquently stated by Schumpeter (1912, p. 74), The banker,therefore,is not so much primarilya middleman,. . . He authorisespeople, in the nameof societyasit were, . . [to innovate]. Stock markets may also influence the acquisition and dissemination of information about firms. As stock markets become larger (Sanford Grossman and Joseph Stiglitz 1980) and more liquid (Albert Kyle 1984; and Bengt Holmstrom and Jean Tirole 1993), market participants may have greater incentives to acquire information about firms. Intuitively, with larger more liquid markets, it is easier for an agent who has acquired information to disguise this private information and make money. Thus, large, liquid stock markets can stimulate the acquisition of information. Moreover, this improved information about firms should improve resource allocation substantially with corresponding implications for economic growth (Merton 1987). However, existing theories have not yet assembled the links of the chain from the functioning of stock markets, to information acquisition, and finally to aggregate long-run economic growth. 12 Indeed, England's advanced financial system also did a good job at identifying profitable ventures in other countries, such as Canada, the United States, and Australiaduring the 19th century. England was able to "export"financial services (as well as financial capital) to many economies with underdeveloped financial systems (Lance Davis and Robert Huttenback 1986). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 696 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Debate still exists over the importance of large, liquid, efficient stock markets in enhancing the creation and distribution information about firms. Stock markets aggregate and disseminate information through published prices. Even agents that do not undertake the costly processes of evaluating firms, managers, and market conditions can observe stock prices that reflect the information obtained by others. This public goods aspect of acquiring information can cause society to devote too few resources to information acquisition. The public goods feature of the information thus disclosed may be sufficiently large, that information gains from large, liquid stock markets are small. Stiglitz (1985) argues that, because stock markets quickly reveal information through posted prices, there will be few incentives for spending private resources to acquire information that is almost immediately publicly available. D. Monitoring Managers and Exerting Corporate Control Besides reducing the costs of acquiring information ex ante, financial contracts, markets, and intermediaries may arise to mitigate the information acquisition and enforcement costs of monitoring firm managers and exerting corporate control ex post, i.e., after financing the activity. For example, firm owners will create financial arrangements that compel firm managers to manage the firm in the best interests of the owners. Also, "outside" creditors banks, equity, and bond holders-that do not manage firms on a day-to-day basis will create financial arrangements to compel inside owners and managers to run firms in accordance with the interests of outside creditors. The absence of financial arrangements that enhance corporate control may impede the mobilization of savings from disparate agents and thereby keep capital from flowing to profitable investments (Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss 1981, 1983). Because this vast literature has been carefully reviewed (Gertler 1988; and Andrei Shleifer and Robert Vishny, forthcoming), this subsection (1) notes a few ways in which financial contracts, markets, and institutions improve monitoring and corporate control, and (2) reviews how these financial arrangements for monitoring influence capital accumulation, resource allocation, and long-run growth. Consider, for example, the simple assumption that it is costly for outsider investors in a project to verify project returns. This creates important frictions that can motivate financial development. Insiders have incentives to misrepresent project returns to outsiders. Given verification costs, however, it is socially inefficient for outsiders to monitor in all circumstances. With "costly state verification" (and other assumptions including risk-neutral borrowers and verification costs that are independent of project quality), the optimal contract between outsiders and insiders is a debt contract (Robert Townsend 1979; and Douglas Gale and Martin Hellwig 1985). Specifically, there is an equilibrium interest rate, r, such that when the project return is sufficiently high, insiders pay r to outsiders and outsiders do not monitor. When project returns are insufficient, the borrower defaults and the lenders pay the monitoring costs to verify the project's return. These verification costs impede investment decisions and reduce economic efficiency. Verification costs imply that outsiders constrain firms from borrowing to expand investment because higher leverage implies greater risk of default and higher verification expenditures by lenders. Thus, collateral and financial contracts that lower monitoring and enforcement costs reduce impediments to efficient investment (Stephen Williamson 1987b; Ben Bernanke and This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 697 Gertler 1989, 1990; Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden 1995).13 Besides particular types of financial contracts, financial intermediaries can reduce information costs even further. If borrowers must obtain funds from many outsiders, financial intermediaries can economize on monitoring costs. The financial intermediary mobilizes the savings of many individuals and lends these resources to project owners. This "delegated monitor" arrangement economizes on aggregate monitoring costs because a borrower is monitored only by the intermediary, not all individual savers (Diamond 1984). Besides reducing duplicate monitoring, a financial system that facilitates corporate control "also makes possible the efficient separation of ownership from management of the firm. This in turn makes feasible efficient specialization in production according to the principle of comparative advantage" (Merton and Bodie 1995, p. 14). The delegated monitor arrangement, however, creates a potential problem: who will monitor the monitor (Stefan Krasa and Anne Villamil 1992)? Savers, however, do not have to monitor the intermediary if the intermediary holds a diversified portfolio (and agents can easily verify that the intermediary's portfolio is well diversified). With a well-diversified portfolio, the intermediary can always meet its promise to pay the deposit interest rate to depositors, so that depositors never have to monitor the bank. Thus, well-diversified financial intermediaries can foster efficient investment by lowering monitoring costs.14 Furthermore, as financial intermediaries and firms develop long-run relationships, this can further lower information acquisition costs. The reduction in information asymmetries can in turn ease external funding constraints and facilitate better resource allocation (Sharpe 1990).15 In terms of long-run growth, financial arrangements that improve corporate control tend to promote faster capital accumulation and growth by improving the allocation of capital (Bencivenga and B. Smith 1993). Besides debt contracts and banks, stock markets may also promote corporate control (Michael Jensen and William Meckling 1976). For example, public trading of shares in stock markets that efficiently reflect information about firms allows owners to link managerial compensation to stock prices. Linking stock performance to manager compensation helps align the interests of managers with those of owners (Diamond and Robert Verrecchia 1982; and Jensen and Kevin Murphy 1990). Similarly, if takeovers are easier in well-developed stock markets and if managers of under-performing firms are fired following a takeover, then better stock markets can promote better corporate control by easing takeovers of poorly managed firms. The threat of a takeover will help align managerial incentives with those of the own- 13 Costly state verification can produce credit rationing. Because higher interest rates are linked with a higher probability of default and monitoring costs, intermediaries may keep rates low and ration credit using non-price mechanisms (Williamson 1986, 1987a). 14Diamond (1984) assumes that intermediaries exist and shows that the intermediaryarrangement economizes on monitoring costs. Williamson (1986) shows how intermediaries arise endogenously. Furthermore, I have only discussed models in which state verification roceeds nonstochastically:if borrowersdefault, ?endersverify. Stochastic monitoring, however, may further reduce verification costs (Bernanke and Gertler 1989; and Boyd and B. Smith 1994). 15The long-run relationships between a banker and client may impose a cost on the client. Because the bank is well informed about the firm, the bank may have bargaining power over the firm's profits. If the bank breaks its ties to the firm, other investors will be reluctant to invest in the firm. Firms may therefore diversify out of bank financing to reduce their vulnerability (RaghurmanRajan1992). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 698 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) ers (David Scharfstein 1988; and Jeremy Stein 1988). I am not aware of models that directly link the role of stock markets in improving corporate governance with long-run economic growth. There are disagreements, however, about the importance of stock marketsin corporate control. Inside investors probably have better information about the corporationthan outsiders. Thus, if wellinformed owners are willing to sell their company, less well informed outsiders may demand a premium to purchase the firm due to the information asymmetry (Stewart Myers and Nicholas Majluf 1984). Thus, asymmetric information may reduce the efficacy of corporate takeovers as a mechanism for exerting corporate control. Stiglitz (1985) makes three additional arguments about takeovers. First, if an acquiring firm expends lots of resources obtaining information, the results of this research will be observed by other market participants when the acquiring firm bids for shares. This will induce others to bid for shares, so that the price rises. The firm that expended resources obtaining information must, therefore, pay a higher price than it would have to pay if "free-riding" firms could not observe its bid. Thus, the rapid public dissemination of costly information will reduce incentives for obtaining information and making effective takeover bids. Second, there is a public good nature to takeovers that may decrease the incentives for takeovers. If the takeover succeeds, and the share price rises, then those original equity holders who did not sell make a big profit without expending resources. This creates an incentive for existing shareholders to not sell if they think the value of the firm will rise following the takeover. Thus, value-increasing takeovers may fail because the acquiring firm will have to pay a high price, which will reduce incentives for researching firms in the hopes of taking them over. Third, current managers often can take strategic actions to deter takeovers and maintain their positions.This arguesagainstan importantrole for liquid stock marketsin promoting sound corporate governance. Moreover, liquid equity markets that facilitate takeovers may hurt resource allocation (Shleifer and Lawrence Summers 1988; and Randall Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny 1990). A takeover typically involves a change in management. Existing implicit contracts between former managers and workers, suppliers, and other stakeholders in the firms do not bind new owners and managers to the same extent that they bound the original managers. Thus, a takeover allows new owners and managers to break implicit agreements and transfer wealth from firm stakeholders to themselves. While new owners may profit, there may be a deterioration in the efficiency of resource allocation. Overall welfare may fall. To the extent that well-functioning equity markets help takeovers, this may allow hostile takeovers that lead to a fall in the efficiency of resource allocation. Furthermore, liquid stock markets may reduce incentives for owners to monitor managers (AmarBhide 1993). By reducing exit costs, stock market liquidity encourages more diffuse ownership with fewer incentives and greater impediments to actively overseeing managers (Shleifer and Vishny 1986). Thus, the theoretical signs on the links in the chain from improvements in stock markets to better corporate control to faster economic growth are still ambiguous.'6 E. Mobilizing Savings Mobilization-pooling-involves the agglomeration of capital from disparate 16 Some research also suggests that excessive stock trading can induce "noise"into the market and hinder efficient resource allocation (Bradford De Long et al. 1989). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 699 savers for investment. Without access to multiple investors, manyproduction processes would be constrained to economically inefficient scales (Erik Sirri and Peter Tufano 1995). Furthermore, mobilization involves the creation of small denomination instruments. These instruments provide opportunities for households to hold diversified portfolios, invest in efficient scale firms, and to increase asset liquidity. Without pooling, household's would have to buy and sell entire firms. By enhancing risk diversification, liquidity, and the size of feasible firms,therefore,mobilizationimprovesresource allocation (SirriandTufano1995). Mobilizing the savings of many disparate savers is costly, however. It involves (a) overcoming the transaction costs associated with collecting savings from different individuals and (b) overcoming the informationalasymmetriesassociated with making savers feel comfortable in relinquishing control of their savings. Indeed, much of Carosso's (1970) history of Investment Banking in America is a description of the diverse and elaborate means employed by investment banks to raise capital. As early as the mid-1880s, some investment banks used their European connections to raise capital abroad for investment in the United States. Other investment banks established close connections with majorbanks and industrialists in the United States to mobilize capital. And, still others used newspaper advertisements, pamphlets, and a vast sales force that traveled through every state and territory selling securities to individual households. Thus, mobilizing resources involved a range of transaction costs. Moreover, "mobilizers" had to convince savers of the soundness of the investments. Toward this end, intermediaries are generally concerned about establishing stellar reputations or government backing, so that savers feel comfortable about entrusting their savings to the intermediary (De Long 1991; and Naomi Lamoreaux 1994). In light of the transaction and information costs associated with mobilizing savings from many agents, numerous financial arrangements may arise to mitigate these frictions and facilitate pooling.17 Specifically, mobilization may involve multiple bilateral contracts between productive units raising capital and agents with surplus resources. The joint stock company in which many individuals invest in a new legal entity, the firm, represents a prime example of multiple bilateral mobilization. To economize on the transaction and information costs associated with multiple bilateral contracts, pooling may also occur through intermediaries as discussed above, where thousands of investors entrust their wealth to intermediaries that invest in hundreds of firms (Sirri and Tufano 1995, p. 83). Financial systems that are more effective at pooling the savings of individuals can profoundly affect economic development. Besides the direct effect of better savings mobilization on capital accumulation, better savings mobilization can improve resource allocation and boost technological innovation (Bagehot 1873, pp. 3-4): Wehaveentirelylostthe ideathatanyundertakinglikelyto pay,andseen to be likely,can perish for want of money;yet no idea was more familiarto our ancestors,or is more commonin mostcountries.A citizenof Long in Queen Elizabeth'stime ... would have thoughtthatit wasno use inventingrailways (if he couldhaveunderstoodwhata railway meant),foryouwouldhavenot been ableto collectthe capitalwithwhichto makethem. At this moment, in colonies and all rude countries,there is no largesum of transferablemoney;thereis notfundfromwhichyou can borrow,and out of whichyou can make immenseworks. 17 See Sections II.C and II.D for citations on the emergence of financialintermediaries. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 700 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Thus, by effectively mobilizing resources for projects, the financial system may play a crucial role in permitting the adoption of better technologies and thereby encouraging growth. This intuition was clarified 100 years later by McKinnon (1973, p. 13): The farmercouldprovidehis ownsavingsto increase slightly the commercialfertilizer thathe is nowusing,andthe returnon this marginalnewinvestmentcouldbe calculated. The importantpoint, however, is the virtual impossibility of a poor farmer's financing from his current savings the whole of the balanced investment needed to adopt the new technology. Access to external financial resources is likely to be necessary over the one or two years when the change takes place. Without this access, the constraint of selffinance sharplybiases investment strategy toward marginal variations within the traditional technology. F. Facilitating Exchange Besides easing savings mobilization and thereby expanding the of set production technologies available to an economy, financial arrangements that lower transaction costs can promote specialization, technological innovation, and growth. The links between facilitating transactions, specialization, innovation, and economic growth were core elements of Adam Smith's (1776) Wealth of Nations. Smith (1776, p. 7) argued that division of labor-specialization-is the principal factor underlying productivity improvements. With greater specialization, workers are more likely to invent better machines or production processes. I shall only observe, therefore, that the invention of all those machines by which labour is so much facilitated and abridged, seems to have been originally owing to the division of labour. Men are much more likely to discover easier and readier methods of attaining any object, when the whole attention of their minds is directed towards that single object, than when it is dissipated among a great variety of things. (Smith 1776, p. 3) The critical issue for our purposes is that the financial system can promote specialization. Adam Smith argued that lower transaction costs would permit greater specialization because specialization requires more transactions than an autarkic environment. Smith phrased his argument about the lowering of transaction costs and technological innovation in terms of the advantages of money over barter (pp. 26-27). Information costs, however, may also motivate the emergence of money. Because it is costly to evaluate the attributes of goods, barter exchange is very costly. Thus, an easily recognizable medium of exchange may arise to facilitate exchange (King and Charles Plosser 1986; and Williamson and Randall Wright 1994).18 The drop in transaction and information costs is not necessarily a one-time fall when economies move to money, however. For example, in the 1800s, " it was primarily the development of institutions that facilitated the exchange of technology in the market that enabled creative individuals to specialize in and become more productive at invention" (Lamoreaux and Sokoloff 1996, p. 17). Thus, transaction and information costs may continue to fall through a variety of mechanisms, so that financial and institutional development continually boost specialization and innovation via the same channels illuminated over 200 years ago by Adam Smith.19 18 This focus on money as a medium of exchange that lowers transaction and information costs by overcoming the "double coincidence of wants problem" and by acting as an easily recognizable medium of exchange enjoys a long history in monetary theory, from Adam Smith (1776), to Stanley Jevons (1875), to Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer (1971), to more formal models as reviewed by Joseph Ostroyand Starr(1990). 19Financial systems can also promote the accumulation of human capitalby lowering the costs of intertemporal trade, i.e., by facilitating borrowing for the accumulationof skills (ThomasCooley and B. Smith 1992; and Jose De Gregorio 1996). If human capital accumulation is not subject to diThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions I Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 701 Modern theorists have attempted to illuminate more precisely the ties between exchange, specialization, and innovation (Greenwood and B. Smith 1997). More specialization requires more transactions. Because each transaction is costly, financial arrangements that lower transaction costs will facilitate greater specialization. In this way, markets that promote exchange encourage productivity gains. There may also be feedback from these productivity gains to financial market development. If there are fixed costs associated with establishing markets, then higher income per capita implies that these fixed costs are less burdensome as a share of per capita income. Thus, economic development can spur the development of financial mar- kets. This approach to linking financial markets with specialization has not yet formally completed Adam Smith's story of innovation. That is, a better market-a market with lower transactions costsdoes not stimulate the invention of new and better production technologies in Greenwood and B. Smith's (1997) model. Instead, lower transaction costs expand the set of "on the shelf' production processes that are economically attractive. Also, the model defines better "market" as a system for supporting more specialized production processes. This does not explain the emergence of financial instruments or institutions that lower transaction costs and thereby produce an environment that naturally promotes specialized production technologies. This is important because we want to understand the two links of the chain: what about the economic environment creates incentives for financial arrangements to arise and to function well or poorly, and what are the implications for economic activity of the emerging financial arrangements? G. A Parable Thus far, I have discussed each financial function in isolation. This, however, may encourage an excessively narrowfocus on individual functions and impede the synthesis of these distinct functions into a coherent understanding of the financial system's role in economic development. This is not a necessary implication. In fact, by identifying the individual functions performed by the financial system, the functional approach can foster a more complete understandingof finance and growth. Earlier authorsoften provided illustrative stories of the ties between finance and development. For example Schumpeter (1912, pp. 58-74) and McKinnon (1973, pp. 5-18) provide broad descriptions-parables-of the roles of the financial system in economic development. Just as Smith (1776) used the pin factory to illustrate the importance of specialization, Schumpeter used the relationship between banker and industrialist to illustrate the importance of the financial system in choosing and adopting new technologies, and McKinnon highlighted its importance in promoting the use of better agriculturaltechniques. However, even Schumpeter and McKinnon did not amalgamateall of the financial functions into their stories of finance and development. Consequently, this subsection synthesizes the individual financial functions into a simple parable about how the financial system affects economic growth. Consider Fred, who has just developed a design for a new truck that extracts rocks from a quarrybetter than existing trucks. His idea for manufacturing trucks requires an intricate assembly line with specialized labor and capital. minishing returns on a social level, financial arrangements that ease human capital creation help accelerate economic growth. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 702 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Highly specialized production processes would be difficult without a medium of exchange. He would find it prohibitively costly to pay his workers and suppliers using barter exchange. Financial instruments and markets that facilitate transactions will allow and promote specialization and thereby permit him to organize his truck assembly line. Moreover, the increased specialization induced by easier transactions may foster learning-by-doing and innovation by the workers specializing on their individual tasks. Production requires capital. Even if Fred had the savings, he would not wish to put all of his savings in one risky investment. Also, he wants ready access to savings for unplanned events; he is reluctant to tie up his savings in the truck project, which will not yield profits, if it does yield profits, for a long time. His distaste for risk and desire for liquidity create incentives for him to (a) diversify the family's investments and (b) not commit too much of his savings to an illiquid project, like producing a new truck. In fact, if Fred must invest disproportionately in his illiquid truck project, he may forgo his plan. Without a mechanism for managing risk, the project may die. Thus, liquidity, risk pooling, and diversification will help him start his innovative project. Moreover, Fred will require outside funding if he has insufficient savings to initiate his truck project. There are problems, however, in mobilizing savings for Fred's truck company. First, it is very costly and time consuming to collect savings from individual savers. Fred does not have the time, connections, and information to collect savings from everyone in his town and neighboring communities even though his idea is sound. Banks and investment banks, however, can mobilize savings more cheaply than Fred due to economies of scale, economies of scope, and experience. Thus, Fred may seek the help of a financial intermediary to mobilize savings for his new truckplant. Two additional problems ("frictions") may keep savings from flowing to Fred's project. To fund the truck plant, the financial intermediaries-and savers in financial intermediaries-require information about the truck design, Fred's ability to implement the design, and whether there is a sufficient demand for better quarrytrucks. This information is difficult to obtain and analyze. Thus, the financial system must be able to acquire reliable information about Fred's idea before funding the truck plant. Furthermore, if potential investors feel that Fred may steal the funds, or run the plant poorly, or misrepresent profits, they will not provide funding. To finance Fred's idea, outside creditors must have confidence that Fred will run the truck plant well. Thus, for Fred to receive funding, the financial system must monitor managers and exert corporate con- trol. While this parable does not contain all aspects of the discussion of financial functions, it provides one cohesive story of how the five financial functions may interact to promote economic develop- ment. H. The Theoryof Finance and Economic Growth:Agenda In describing the conceptual links between the functioning of the financial system and economic growth, I highlighted areas needing additional research. Two more areas are worth emphasizing. First, we do not have a sufficiently rigorous understanding of the emergence, development, and economic implications of different financial structures. Financial structure-the mix of financial contracts, markets, and institutions-varies across countries and This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 703 changes as countries develop (Boyd and B. Smith 1996). Yet, we do not have adequate theories of why different financial structures emerge or why financial structures change. Differences in legal tradition (Rafael LaPortaet al. 1996) and differences in national resource endowments that produce different political and institutional structures (Stanley Engerman and Sokoloff 1996) might be incorporatedinto future models of financial development. Furthermore, economists need to develop an analyticalbasis for makingcomparisonsof financialstructures; we need models that elucidate the conditions, if any, under which different financialstructuresare better at mitigating information and transaction costs. A second area needing additional research involves the influence of the level and growth rate of the economy on the financial system. Some models assume that there is a fixed cost to joining financial intermediaries. Economic growth then reduces the importance of this fixed cost and more people join. Thus, economic growth provides the means for the formation of growth-promoting financial intermediaries, while the formation of financial intermediaries accelerates growth by enhancing the allocation of capital. In this way, financial and economic development are jointly determined (Greenwood and Jovanovic 1990). Economic development may affect the financial system in other ways that have not yet been formallymodeled. For example, the costs and skills required to evaluate production technologies and monitor managers may be very different in a service-oriented economy from that of a manufacturing-based economy or an agricultural-based economy. Building on Hugh Patrick (1966), Greenwood and Jovanovic (1990), and Greenwood and Smith (1997), future research may improve our understandingof the impactof growthon financialsystems. III. Evidence A. The Questions Are differences in financial development and structure importantly associated with differences in economic growth rates? To assess the nature of the finance-growth relationship, I first describe research on the links between the functioning of the financial system and economic growth, capital accumulation, and technological change. Then, I evaluate existing evidence on the ties between financial structure-the mix of financial markets and intermediaries-and the functioning of the financial system. A growing body of work demonstrates a strong, positive link between financial development and economic growth, and there is even evidence that the level of financial development is a good predictor of future economic development. Evidence on the relationship between financial structure and the functioning of the financial system, however, is more inconclusive. B. TheLevel of Financial Development and Growth:Cross-Country Studies Consider first the relationship between economic growth and aggregate measures of how well the financial system functions. The seminal work in this area is by Goldsmith (1969). He uses the value of financial intermediary assets divided by GNP to gauge financial development under the assumption that the size of the financial system is positively correlated with the provision and quality of financial services. Using data on 35 countries from 1860 to 1963 (when available) Goldsmith (1969, p. 48) finds: (1) a rough parallelism can be observed between economic and financial development if periods of several decades are considered; [and] (2) there are even indications in the few countries for which the data are availablethat This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 704 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) periods of more rapid economic growth have been accompanied, though not without exception, by an above-average rate of financial development. Goldsmith's work, however, has several weaknesses: (a) the investigation involves limited observations on only 35 countries; (b) it does not systematically control for other factors influencing economic growth (Levine and David Renelt 1992); (c) it does not examine whether financial development is associated with productivity growth and capital accumulation; (d) the size of financialintermediaries may not accurately measure the functioning of the financial system; and (e) the close association between the size of the financial system and economic growth does not identify the direction of causality.20 Recently, researchers have taken steps to address some of these weaknesses. For example, King and Levine (1993a, 1993b, 1993c) study 80 countries over the period 1960-1989, systematically control for other factors affecting longrun growth, examine the capital accumulation and productivity growth channels, construct additional measures of the level of financial development, and analyze whether the level of financial development predicts long-run economic growth, capital accumulation, and productivity growth. (Also, see Alan Gelb 1989; Gertler and Andrew Rose 1994; Nouriel Roubini and Xavier Sala-iMartin 1992; Easterly 1993; and the overview by Pagano 1993.) They use four measures of "the level of financial development" to mioreprecisely measure the functioning of the financial system than Goldsmith's size measure. Table 1 summarizes the values of these measures relative to real per capita GDP (RGDP) in 1985. The first measure, DEPTH, measures the size of financial intermediaries and equals liquid liabilities of the financial system (currency plus demand and interest-bearing liabilities of banks and nonbank financial intermediaries) divided by GDP. As shown, citizens of the richest countries-the top 25 percent on the basis of income per capitaheld about two-thirds of a year's income in liquid assets in formal financial intermediaries, while citizens of the poorest countries-the bottom 25 percent-held only a quarter of a year's income in liquid assets. There is a strong correlation between real per capita GDP and DEPTH. The second measure of financial development, BANK, measures the degree to which the central bank versus commercial banks are allocating credit. BANK equals the ratio of bank credit divided by bank credit plus central bank domestic assets. The intuition underlying this measure is that banks are more likely to provide the five financial functions than central banks. There are two notable weaknesses with this measure, however. Banks are not the only financial intermediaries providing valuable financial functions and banks may simply lend to the government or public enterprises. BANK is greater than 90 percent in the richest quartile of countries. In contrast, commercial banks and central banks allocate about the same amount of credit in the poorest quartile of countries. The third and fourth measures partially address concerns about the allocation of credit. The third measures, PRIVATE,equals the ratio of credit allocated to private enterprises to total domestic credit (excluding credit to banks). The fourth measure, PRIVY, equals credit to private enterprises divided by 20 Goldsmith (1969) recognized these weaknesses, e.g., "there is no possibility, however, of establishing with confidence the direction of the causal mechanisms, i.e., of deciding whether financial factors were responsible for the acceleration of economic development or whether financial development reflected economic growth whose mainspringsmust be sought elsewhere" (p. 48). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 705 TABLE1 FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND REAL PER CAPITA GDPIN 1985 Correlation withRealper CapitaGDPin Indictors Veryrich Rich Poor Verypoor 1985 (P-value) DEPTH 0.67 0.51 0.39 0.26 0.51 (0.0001) BANK 0.91 0.73 0.57 0.52 0.58 (0.0001) PRIVATE 0.71 0.58 0.47 0.37 0.51 (0.0001) PRIVY 0.53 0.31 0.20 0.13 0.70 (0.0001) RGDP85 13053 2376 754 241 Observations 29 29 29 29 Source: KingandLevine(1993a) Veryrich: RealGDPperCapita> 4998 Rich: RealGDPperCapita> 1161and<4998 Poor: RealGDPperCapita> 391and< 1161 Verypoor: RealGDPperCapita< 391 DEPTH = Liquidliabilitiesto GDP BANK= Depositmoneybankdomesticcreditdividedbydepositmoney bank+ centralbankdomesticcredit PRIVATE= Claimsonthe non-financialprivatesectorto domesticcredit PRIVY= Grossclaimsonprivatesectorto GDP RGDP85= RealpercapitaGDPin 1985(inconstant1987dollars) GDP. The assumption underlying these measures is that financial systems that allocate more credit to private firms are more engaged in researching firms, exerting corporate control, providing risk management services, mobilizing savings, and facilitating transactionsthan financial systems that simply funnel credit to the government or state owned enterprises. As depicted in Table 1, there is a positive, statistically significant correlation between real per capita GDP and the extent to which loans are directed to the private sector. King and Levine (1993b, 1993c) then assess the strength of the empirical relationship between each of these four indicators of the level of financial development averaged over the 1960-1989 period, F, and three growth indicators also averaged over the 1960-1989 period, G. The three growth indicators are as follows: (1) the average rate of real per capita GDP growth, (2) the average rate of growth in the capital stock per person, and (3) total productivity growth, which is a "Solow residual" defined as real per capita GDP growth minus (0.3) times the growth rate of the capital stock per person. In other words, if F(i) represents the value of the ith indicator of financial development (DEPTH, BANK, PRIVY,PRIVATE)averaged over the period 1960-1989, GO) represents the value of the jth growth indicator (per capita GDP growth, per capita capital stock growth, or productivity growth) averaged over the period 1960- 1989, andX represents a matrixof conditioning information to control for other factors associated with economic growth (e.g., income per capita, education, political stability, indicators of exchange rate, trade, fiscal, and monetary policy), This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 706 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) TABLE2 GROWTHANDCONTEMPORANEOUSFINANCIALINDICATORS,1960-1989 DependantVariable DEPTH BANK PRIVATE PRIVY RealPerCapitaGDP Growth 0.024*** 0.032*** 0.034*** 0.032*** [0.007] [0.005] [0.002] [0.002] R2 0.5 0.5 0.52 0.52 RealPerCapitaCapitalStockGrowth 0.022*** 0.022** 0.020** 0.025*** [0.001] [0.012] [0.011] [0.001] R2 0.65 0.62 0.62 0.64 ProductivityGrowth 0.018** 0.026** 0.027*** 0.025*** [0.026] [0.010] [0.003] [0.006] R2 0.42 0.43 0.45 0.44 Source:KingandLevine(1993b) * significantatthe 0.10level,** significantatthe 0.05level, significantatthe 0.01level. [p-valuesinbrackets] Observations = 77 DEPTH = Liquidliabilitiesto GDP BANK= Depositbankdomesticcreditdividedbydepositmoneybank+ centralbankdomestic credit PRIVATE= Claimsonthe non-financialprivatesectorto totalclaims PRIVY= Grossclaimsonprivatesectorto GDP ProductivityGrowth= RealPerCapitaGDP Growth- (0.3)*RealPerCapitaCapitalStockGrowth Otherexplanatoryvariablesincludedin eachofthe12regressions:logofinitialincome,logof initialsecondary schoolenrollmentrate,ratioof governmentconsumptionexpendituresto GDP,inflationrate,andratioof export plusimportsto GDP. then the following 12 regressions are run on a cross-section of 77 countries: G(j)=ac+fF(i)+yX+ (1) There is a strong positive relationship between each of the four financial development indicators, F(i), and the three growth indicators G(i), long-run real per capita growth rates, capital accumulation, and productivity growth. Table 2 summarizes the results on the 12 ,'s. Not only are all the financial development coefficients statistically significant, the sizes of the coefficients imply an economically important relationship. Ignoring causality, the coefficient of 0.024 on DEPTH implies that a country that increased DEPTH from the mean of the slowest growing quartile of countries (0.2) to the mean of the fastest growing quartile of countries (0.6) would have increased its per capita growth rate by almost one percent per year. This is large. The difference between the slowest growing 25 percent of countries and the fastest growing quartile of countries is about five percent per annum over this 30 year period. Thus, the rise in DEPTH alone eliminates 20 percent of this growth difference. Finally, to examine whether finance simply follows growth, King and Levine (1993b) study whether the value of financial depth in 1960 predicts the rate of economic growth, capital accumulation, and productivity improvements over the next 30 years. Table 3 summarizes some of the results. In the three regressions reported in Table 3, the dependent variableis, respectively, realper This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 707 TABLE3 GROWTHAND INITIAL FINANCIAL DEPTH, 1960-1989 PerCapitaGDP PerCapitaCapital PerCapitaProductivity Growth,1960-1989 Growth,1960-1989 Growth,1960-1989 Constant 0.035*** 0.002 0.034*** [0.001] [0.682] [0.001] Log(RealGDPper -0.016*** -0.004* -0.015*** Personin 1960) [0.001] [0.068] [0.001] Log(Secondaryschool 0.013*** 0.007*** 0.011*** enrollmentin 1960) [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] Government 0.07* 0.049* 0.056* consumption/GDPin 1960 [0.051] [0.064] [0.076] Inflationin 1960 0.037 0.02 0.029 [0.239] [0.238] [0.292] (ImportsplusExports)/GDP -0.003 -0.001 -0.003 in 1960 [0.604] [0.767] [0.603] DEPTH (liquidliabilities) 0.028*** 0.019*** 0.022*** in 1960 [0.001] [0.001] [0.001] R2 0.61 0.63 0.58 Source: KingandLevine(1993b) * significantatthe 0.10level, "*significantatthe 0.05level, significantatthe 0.01level. [p-valuesinbrackets] Observations = 57 capita GDP growth, real per capita capital stock growth, and productivitygrowth averaged over the period 1960-1989. The financial indicator in each of these regressions is the value of DEPTH in 1960. The regressions indicate that financial depth in 1960 is significantly correlated with each of the growth indicators averaged over the period 1960- 1989.21 These results, plus those from more sophisticated time series studies, suggest that the initial level of financial development is a good predictor of subsequent rates of economic growth, physical capital accumulation, and economic efficiency improvementsover the next 30 yearseven aftercontrollingforincome, education, political stability, and measures of monetary,trade, and fiscal policy.22 21 There is an insufficient number of observations on BANK, PRIVATE,and PRIVYin 1960 to extend the analysis in Table 3 to these variables. Thus, King and Levine (1993b) use pooled, cross section, time series data. For each country, data permitting, they use data averagedover the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s; thus, there are potentially three observations per country. They then relate the value of growth averaged over the 1960s with the value of, for example, BANKin 1960 and so on for the other two decades. They restrict the coefficients to be the same across decades. They find that the initial level of financial development is a good predictor of subsequent rates of economic growth, capital accumulation, and economic efficiency improvements over the next ten years after controlling for many other factors associated with long-run growth. 22 These broad cross-country results hold even when using instrumentalvariables-primarily indicators of the legal treatment of creditors taken from LaPorta et al. 1996-to extract the exogenous component of financial development (Levine 1997). Furthermore, though disagreement exists (Woo Jung 1986 and Philip Arestis and Panicos Demetriades 1995), many time-series investigations find that financial sector development Granger-causes economic performance (Paul Wachtel Rousseau 1995). These results are particularlystrong when using measures of the valueadded provided by the financial system instead of measures of the size of the financial system (Klaus Neusser and MauriceKugler 1996). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 708 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) The relationship between the initial level of financial development and growth is large. For example, the estimated coefficients suggest that if in 1960 Bolivia had increased its financial depth from 10 percent of GDP to the mean value for developing countries in 1960 (23 percent), then Bolivia would have grown about 0.4 percent faster per annum, so that by 1990 real per capita GDP would have been about 13 percent larger than it was.23Thus, finance does not merely follow economic activity. The strong link between the level of financial development and the rate of long-run economic growth does not simply reflect contemporaneous shocks that affect both financial development and economic performance. There is a statistically significant and economically large empirical relationship between the initial level of financial development and future rates of long-run growth, capital accumulation, and productivity improvements. Furthermore, insufficient financial development has sometimes created a "povertytrap" and thus become a severe obstacle to growth even when a country has established other conditions (macroeconomic stability, openness to trade, educational attainment, etc.) for sustained economic development (JeanClaude Berthelemy and Aristomene Varoudakis1996). Some recent work has extended our knowledge about the causal relationships between financial development and economic growth. For example, Rajan and Luigi Zingales (1996) assume that financial markets in the United States are relatively frictionless. This benchmark country then defines each industry'sefficient demand for external finance (investment minus internal cash flow). They then examine industries across a large sample of countries and test whether the industries that are more dependent on external finance (in the United States) grow relatively faster in countries that begin the sample period with better developed financial systems. They find that industries that rely heavily on external funding grow comparatively faster in countries with well-developed intermediaries (as measured by PRIVY) and stock markets (as measured by stock market capitalization) than they do in countries that start with relatively weak financial systems. Similarly, using firmlevel data from 30 countries, Asli Demirguc-Kunt and Vojislav Maksimovic (1996b) argue that firms with access to more developed stock markets grow at faster rates than they could have grown without this access. Furthermore, when individual states of the United States relaxed intrastate branching restrictions, this boosted bank lending quality and accelerated real per capita growth rates even after controlling for other growth determinants (Jith Jayaratne and Philip Strahan 1996). Thus, using firm- and industrial-level data for a broad crosssection of countries and data on individual states of the United States, recent research presents evidence consistent with the view that the level of financial development materially affects the rate and structure of economic de- velopment. Not surprisingly,these empirical studies do not unambiguously resolve the issue of causality. Financial development may predict growth simply because financial systems develop in anticipation of future economic growth. Furthermore, differences in political systems, legal traditions (LaPortaet al. 1996), or institutions (Engerman and Sokoloff 1996; Douglass North 1981) may be driving both financial development and economic growth rates. Nevertheless, the body of evidence would tend to push 23 These examples do not consider causal issues or how to increase financialdevelopment. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 709 many skeptics toward the view that the finance-growth link is a first-order relationship and that difference in financial development can alter economic growth rates over ample time horizons. C. Country-Case Studies Country-case studies provide a rich complement to cross-country comparisons. For example, Rondo Cameron et al. (1967) dissect the historical relationships between banking development and the early stages of industrialization for England (1750-1844), Scotland (1750- 1845), France (1800-1870), Belgium (1800-1875), Germany (1815-1870), Russia (1860-1914), and Japan (1868- 1914). These country-case studies do not use formal statistical analysis. Instead, the researchers carefully examine the legal, economic, and financial linkages between banks and industry during the industrialization of these seven countries. Typically, the case studies start by describing the political system, economic conditions, and financial structure at the start of the period of analysis.Then, they provide a detailed description of the evolution of the financial system during a period of rapid economic development. Finally, they document critical interactions among financial intermediaries, financial markets, government policies, and the financing of industrialization. While providing an informative complement to broad cross country comparisons, country-case studies rely heavily on subjective evaluations of banking system performance and fail to systematically control for other elements determining economic development. While emphasizing the analytical limitations of countrycase studies, Cameron (1967b) concludes that especially in Scotland and Japan, but also in Belgium, Germany, England, and Russia, the banking system played a positive, growth-inducingrole. Debate exists, however. Consider the case of Scotland between 1750 and 1845. Scotland began the period with per capita income of less than one-half of England's. By 1845, however, per capita income was about the same. While recognizing that the "dominantpolitical event affecting Scotland's potentialities for economic development was the Union of 1707, which made Scotland an integral part of the United Kingdom," Cameron (1967a, p. 60), argues that Scotland's superior banking system is one of the few noteworthy features that can help explain its comparatively rapid growth.24 Other analysts disagree with the "facts" underlying this conclusion. Some researchers suggest that England did not suffer from a dearth of financial services because nonfinancial enterprises provided financial services in England that Cameron's (1967a) measures of formal financial intermediation omit. Others argue that Scotland had rich natural resources, a well-educated work force, access to British colonial markets, and started from a much lower level of income per capita than England. Consequently, it is not surprisingthat Scotland enjoyed a period of rapid convergence toward England's income per capita level. Finally, still other researchers disagree with the premise that Scotland had a well-functioning financial system and emphasize the deficiencies in the Scottish system (Sidney Pollard and Dieter Ziegler 1992). Thus, although Andrew Kerr first argued in 1884 that Scotland enjoyed a better banking system than England from 1750 until 1844, the debate about whether Scottish banking explains its faster economic growth over the period 1750-1845 continues today. 24 It is also worth noting that Scottish banking was comparativelystable over this period, suffering fewer and less severe panics than its southern neighbor. For more on Scottish banking, see Sydney Checkland (1975) and Tyler Cowen and Randall Kroszner(1989). This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 710 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) The relationship between financial and economic development has been carefully analyzed for many other countries. For example, Stephen Haber (1991, 1996) compares industrial and capital market development in Brazil, Mexico, and the United States between 1830 and 1930. He finds that capital market development affected industrial composition and national economic performance. Specifically, Haber shows that when Brazil overthrew the monarchy in 1889 and formed the First Republic, it also dramatically liberalized restrictions on Brazilianfinancial markets.The liberalization gave more firms easier access to external finance. Industrial concentration fell and industrial production boomed. While Mexico also liberalized financial sector policies, the liberalization was much more mild under the Diaz dictatorship (1877-1911), which "relied on the financial and political support of a small in-group of powerful financial capitalists"(p. 561). As a result, the decline in concentration and the increase in economic growth was much weaker in Mexico than it was in Brazil. Haber (1996, p. 40) concludes that "differences in capital market development had a significant impact on the rate of growth of industry. . . . [and that a] lack of access to institutional sources of capital because of poorly developed capital markets was a non-negligible obstacle to industrial development in the nineteenth cen- tury."25 Finally, but perhaps most influencially, McKinnon's (1973) seminal book Money and Capital in Economic Development studies the relationship between the financial system and economic development in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Germany, Korea, Indonesia, and Taiwan in the post World War II period. McKinnon interprets the mass of evidence emerging from these country-case studies as strongly suggesting that better functioning financial systems support faster economic growth. Disagreement exists over many of these individual cases, and it is extremely difficult to isolate the importance of any single factor in the process of economic growth.26 Thus, any statements about causality are-and will remain-largely impressionistic and specific to particular countries and specific periods. Nonetheless, the body of country-studies suggests that, while the financial system responds to demands from the nonfinancialsector, well-functioning financial systems have, in some cases during some time periods, greatly spurred economic growth. D. Financial Functions and Growth: Liquidity and Risk I now turn to evidence on the ties between measures of the individual financial functions and economic growth. First, consider liquidity. Deposit-taking banks can provide liquidity by issuing liquid demand deposits and makingilliquid, long-term investments. Isolating this liquidity function from the other financial functions performed by banks, however, has proven prohibitively difficult. In contrast, economists have studied extensively the effects of the liquidity of an individual security on its price. Substantial evidence suggests a positive correlation between the liquidity of an asset 25 Interestingly, these political and legal impediments to financial development are apparently difficult to change. In Mexico, the largest three banks control the same fraction of commercial banking activity today, about two-thirds, as they did 100 years ago. Also, Mexico has the lowest ranking of the legal protection of minority shareholder rights of any country in La Porta et al.'s (1996) detailed comparison of 49 countries, which may facilitate the concentration of economic decision making. 26 For more on Mexico see Robert Bennett (1963). For more on Asia, see Cole and YungPark (1983), Park (1993), and Patrick and Park(1994). Fry (1995) provides additionalcitations. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 711 TABLE4 STOCK MARKET LIQUIDITY MEASURES: SELECTED COUNTRIES, ANNUAL AVERAGES 1976-1993 Turnover Value PerCapita Ratio TradedRatio GDP Growth Low-income Bangladesh 0.015 0.000 1.89% Coted'lvoire 0.028 0.001 -2.50% Egypt 0.060 0.030 3.56% India 0.537 0.036 2.43% Nigeria 0.006 0.000 -0.11% Pakistan 0.105 0.008 3.13% Zimbabwe 0.059 0.010 -0.97% Lower-middle-income Colombia 0.087 0.004 1.95% CostaRica 0.013 0.001 0.89% Indonesia 0.193 0.010 4.18% Jordan 0.154 0.085 3.01% Philippines 0.250 0.026 0.21% Thailand 0.739 0.144 5.90% Turkey 0.207 0.026 2.32% Upper-middle-income Argentina 0.266 0.013 0.22% Brazil 0.355 0.041 0.65% Chile 0.060 0.021 3.61% Korea 0.832 0.186 9.67% Malaysia 0.230 0.243 4.27% Mauritius 0.059 0.003 1.76% Mexico 0.498 0.044 0.85% Portugal 0.108 0.014 2.85% High-income Australia 0.256 0.124 1.57% Germany 0.704 0.156 0.95% GreatBritian 0.349 0.253 1.75% HongKong 0.372 0.471 6.20% Israel 0.669 0.144 1.72% Italy 0.253 0.028 2.68% Japan 0.469 0.406 3.42% Netherlands 0.490 0.123 1.43% Norway 0.318 0.059 2.48% Spain 0.216 0.045 1.75% Switzerland 0.467 0.442 1.16% UnitedStates 0.493 0.299 1.67% Sources:InternationalFinanceCorporation,andMorganStanleyCapitalInternational TurnoverRatio=Valueof DomesticEquitiesTradedon DomesticExchangesDividedbyMarketCapitalization ValueTradedRatio=Valueof DomesticEquitiesTradedon DomesticExchangesDividedbyGDPIncome classificationsfromtheWorldBank's1995WorldDevelopmentReport Low-incomeeconomies= averageGNPpercapitaof $380in 1993 Lower-middle-incomeeconomies= averageGNPpercapitaof $1,590in 1993 Upper-middle-incomeeconomies= averageGNPpercapitaof $4,370in 1993 High-incomeeconomies= averageGNPpercapitaof $23,090in 1993 This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 712 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) and its price (e.g., Yakov Amihud and Haim Mendelson 1989; and Gregory Kadlec and John McConnell 1994). Put differently, agents must be compensated with a lower price for purchasing an asset that is difficult to sell. These security-level studies of the relationship between the liquidity of individual securities and their prices, however, do not link liquidity with national long run growth rates. To evaluate the relationship between stock market liquidity and national growth rates, capital accumulation rates, and rates of technological change, Levine and Sara Zervos (1996) build on Raymond Atje and Jovanovic's (1993) study and focus on two measures of liquidity for a broad cross-section of 49 countries over the period 1976-1993. The first liquidity indicator, the value traded ratio, equals the total value of shares traded on a country's stock exchanges divided by GDP. The value traded ratio measures trading relative to the size of the economy. While not a direct measure of trading costs or the uncertainty associated with trading and settling equity transactions, theoretical models of liquidity and growth directly motivate the value traded ratio (Bencivenga, B. Smith, and Starr 1995). As shown in Table 4, the value traded ratio varies considerably across countries. For example, the United States had an average annual value traded ratio of 0.3 during the 1976-1993 period, while for Mexico and India it was about 0.04. The second indicator, the turnover ratio, equals the total value of shares traded on a country's stock exchanges divided by stock market capitalization (the value of listed shares on the country's exchanges). The turnover ratio measures tradingrelative to the size of the market. It also exhibits substantial cross-country variability. Very active markets such as Japan and the United States have turnover ratios of almost 0.5, while for less liquid markets, such as Bangladesh, Chile, and Egypt they are 0.06 or less.27 The turnover ratio may differ from the value traded ratio because a small, liquid market will have high turnover ratio but a small value traded ratio. For example, India's average turnover ratio of 0.5 over the 1976-1993 is greater than the United States', but India's value traded ratio is about one-tenth the size of the United States'. These measures seek to measure liquidity on a macroeconomic scale: the objective is to measure the degree to which agents can cheaply, quickly, and confidently trade ownership claims of a large percentage of the economy's productive technologies.28 The researchers then assess the strength of the empirical relationship between each liquidity measure and the three growthindicators:economic growth, capital accumulation, and productivity growth. They conduct a cross-country analysis with one observation per country. Namely, six basic regressions are run: economic growth, capital accumulation, and productivity growth averaged over the 1976-1993 period are regressed first on the value traded ratio in 1976 and then on the turnover ratio in 1976 while controlling for various factors associated with economic growth (initial income per capita, education, political stability, indicators of exchange rate, trade, fiscal, and monetary policy) to see whether stock market liquidity predicts subsequent economic growth. Importantly, the level of banking sector development (bank credit to private enterprises divided by GDP) measured in 27 Note, Germany's very large turnover ratio (0.7) reflects the explosion in stock market transactions duringunification. 28 Levine and Zervos (1996) also construct and examine two measures of stock trading relative to stock price movements: (1) the value traded ratio divided by stock returnvolatility, and (2) the turnover ratio divided by stock returnvolatility. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 713 TABLE 5 GROWTHAND INITIAL STOCK MARKETLIQUIDITY,1976-1993 Value Traded Turnover Dependant Variable Ratio Ratio Real Per Capita GDP Growth 0.098*** 0.027*** [0.003] [0.006] AdjustedR2 0.33 0.34 RealPerCapitaCapitalStockGrowth 0.093*** 0.022*** [0.005] [0.023] AdjustedR2 0.38 0.35 ProductivityGrowth 0.075*** 0.020** [0.001] [0.030] AdjustedR2 0.21 0.21 Source:LevineandZervos(1996) * significantatthe 0.10level,** significantatthe 0.05level, significantatthe 0.01level. [p-valuesinbrackets] Observations = 42 ValueTradedRatio=Valueof domesticequitytransactionson domesticstockexchangesdividedbyGDP TurnoverRatio= Valueof domesticequitytransactionson domesticstockexchangesdividedbydomesticmarket capitalization. Otherexplanatoryvariablesincludedin eachofthesixregressions: logofinitialincome,logofinitialsecondaryschoolenrollment,initialratioof governmentexpendituresto GDP,initialinflationrate,initialblackmarketexchangeratepremium,initialratioof commercialbanklendingtoprivate enterprisesdividedbyGDP. 1976 is included in the regressions to assess the independent link between stock market liquidity and growth after controlling for other aspects of financial development. The results are summarized in Table 5. The initial level of stock market liquidity-measured either by the turnoverratio or the value traded ratiois a statistically significant predictor of economic growth, capital accumulation, and productivitygrowth over the next 18 years. The sizes of the coefficients also suggest an economically meaningful relationship. For example, the results imply that if Mexico had had the sample average value traded ratio in 1976 (0.044) instead of its realized 1976 value (0.004), per capita GDP would have grown at a 0.4 percent faster rate (0.04*0.098). Accumulating over the 18 year period, this implies each Mexican would have enjoyed an almost 8 percent higher income in 1994. The results are consistent with the views that the liquidity services provided by stock markets are independently important for long-run growth and that stock markets provide different financial services from those provided by financial intermediaries (or else they would not both enter the growth regressions significantly).29 Besides the difficulty of assigning a causal role to stock market liquidity, there are important limitations to measuring it accurately (Sanford Grossman and Merton Miller 1988; and Stephen 29 Stock market size, as measured by market capitalizationdivided by GDP, is not robustly correlated with growth, capital accumulation, and productivityimprovements. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 714 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) Wells 1994). Theory suggests that economies will benefit from the ability to trade ownership of an economy's productive technologies easily. Stock markets, however, are only one mechanism for providing liquidity. Banks and bond marketsmay also provide liquidity. Thus, measures of stock market liquidity might omit important financial arrangements for providing liquidity. Moreover, the liquidity indicators measure stock transactions on a country's national stock exchanges. The physical location of the stock market,however, should not necessarily matter. That is, Californian savers and firms would probably not have greater access to liquidity if the New York Stock Exchange were to move to Los Angeles. Thus, measures of the trading of equities on a country's exchanges may not gauge fully the degree of stock market liquidity available to the economy. This measurement problem will increase over time if economies become more financially integrated and firms list and issue shares on foreign ex- changes. Besides liquidity risk, the financial system also provides mechanisms for hedging and trading the idiosyncratic risk associated with individual projects, firms, industries, sectors, and countries. While a vast literature examines the pricing of risk, there exists very little empirical evidence that directly links risk diversification services with long-run economic growth. Moreover, the only study of the relationship between economic growth and the ability of investors to diversify risk internationally through equity markets yields inconclusive results (Levine and Zervos 1996). One common weakness in empirical work on liquidity, idiosyncratic risk, and economic growth is that it focuses on equity markets. Bond marketsand financial intermediaries may also provide mechanisms for diversifying risk. Indeed, technological, regulatory, and tax differences across countries may imply that different financial structures arise to provide liquidity and risk diversification vehicles. For example, in one economy the costs of establishing an intermediary may be high while the costs of conducting equity transactions are low. The reverse may hold in a second economy. The first economy may provide liquidity and risk diversification services primarily through equity markets, while the second does it through financial intermediaries. The first economy has an active stock exchange, so that existing empirical studies would classify it as providing substantial liquidity and risk diversification services. In contrast, existing studies would classify the second economy as financially underdeveloped. Thus, measuring the performance of one part of the financial system may generate a misleading indicator of the functioning of the whole financial system. E. Financial Functions and Growth: Information Theory strongly suggests that financial intermediaries play an important role in researching productive technologies before investment and monitoring managers and projects after funneling capital to those projects. Although it is very difficult to measure whether a country's financial system is comparatively adept at reducing information acquisition costs firm level studies provide insights into the role played by financial intermediaries in easing information asymmetries (Schiantarelli 1995). Theory suggests that as the costs to outsiders of acquiring information about a firm rise, a firm's investment decisions become more tightly constrained by retained earnings and current cash flow. Thus, studies test whether the investment decisions of firms with particular traits that proxy for the costs to outsiders of acquiring inforThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 715 mation are more sensitive to cash flow than firms without those traits. The sample selection criterion varies across stud- ies. The empirical evidence suggests that the investment decisions of firms with more severe asymmetric information problems are more sensitive to cash flow than those where it is less expensive for outsiders to monitor. This conclusion holds when firms are classified according to whether they have received bond ratings (Toni Whited 1992; Charles Calomiris, Charles Himmelberg, and Wachtel 1995), whether they are issuing large or small dividends (Steven Fazzari, Glen Hubbard, and Bruce Peterson 1988; Hubbard, Anil Kashyap, and Whited 1995), whether they are large or small (James Tybout 1983; Gertler and Simon Gilchrist 1994), whether they place a relatively high or low shadow value on internal funds based on their response to taxes (Calomiris and Hubbard 1995), and whether regulations restrict bank credit allocation (Fidel Jaramillo, Schiantarelli, Weiss 1996; John Harris, Schiantarelli, and Miranda Siregar 1994). In sum, when outsiders find it expensive to evaluate and fund particular firms, those firms find it relatively difficult to raise capital for investment and rely disproportionately on internal sources of finance. Thus, financial innovations or policies that lower information asymmetries ease firm financing constraints on more efficient firms. More relevant for this section, a large body of work shows that when firms have close ties to financial intermediaries, this reduces information costs and eases firm financing constraints. Specifically, firms with close ties to banks tend to be less constrained in their investment decisions than those with less intimate, less mature banking relationships as shown for Japan (Takeo Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein 1990), Italy (Schiantarelli and Alessandro Sembenelli 1996), and the United States (Petersen and Rajan 1994). Furthermore, borrowers with longer banking relationships pay lower interest rates and are less likely to pledge collateral than those with less mature banking relationships (Petersen and Rajan 1994; and Allen Berger and GregoryUdell 1995). Finally, stock price evidence also indicates that banks produce valuable, private information about borrowers. When banks sign loan agreements with borrowers, borrower-firm stock prices respond positively (Christopher James 1987; Scott Lummar and McConnell 1989; and James and Peggy Weir 1990). The value of the information obtained by banks about firms can also be exemplified by Continental Illinois' troubles in the mid-1980s. MyronSlovin, Marie Sushka, and John Polonchek (1993) show that the banks' impending insolvency negatively affected the stock prices of its client firms and that the FDIC's rescue efforts positively affected the stock prices of those same clients. These findings are consistent with the view that the durability of bank-borrower relationship is valuable. The evidence directly indicates an important role for financial intermediaries in reducing informational asymmetries between firm insiders and outside investors. Indirectly, the evidence suggests that countries with financial institutions that are effective at relieving information barriers will promote faster economic growth through more investment than countries with financial systems that are less effective at obtaining and processing information. F. Patterns of Financial Development I now turn to the question: Does financial structure change as countries develop and does it differ across countries? Again, Goldsmith pioneered the crossThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 716 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) 180- 160- 140- 0120- 0 D100 80- 60- 40- 20- 0- r Financial Central Commercial Nonbank StockMarket StockMarket Depth BankAssets BankAssets Assets Capitalization Trading LowIncome MiddleIncome HighIncome Figure 2. FinancialStructurein Low-, Middle-, and High-Income Economies, 1990 Sources: IMF (InternationalFinancial Statistics),IFC (Em-ergingMarketsData Base), andindividual countryreportsby centralbanks,bankingcommissions,and stockexchanges. Notes: (1) The dataarefor 12 low-income economies (Bangladesh,Egypt, Ghana,Guyana,India, Indonesia,Kenya,Nigeria,Pakistan,Zaire,Zambia,andZimbabwe),22 middle-income economies (Argentina,Bolivia,Brazil,Chile, Colombia,CostaRica,the Dominican Republic,El Salvador,Greece, Guatemala,Jamaica,the Republicof Korea,Malaysia,Mexico,Paraguay,The Philippines,Taiwan,Thailand, Tunisia,Turkey,Uruguay,andVenezuela),and 14 high-income economies (Australia,Canada,Denmark, Finland, Germany,Italy,Japan,The Netherlands,Singapore,Spain,Sweden, the United Kingdom,andthe United States)datapermitting.In 1990, low-income economies had an averageGDP per capitaof $490; middle-income economies, $2,740;andhigh-income economies, $20,457. (2) Non-bankfinancialinstitutionsinclude insurancecompanies,pension funds, mutualfunds,brokerage houses, andinvestmentbanks. (3) Financialdepth is measuredby currencyheld outside financialinstitutionsplus demanddeposits and interest-bearingliabilitiesof banksandnonbankfinancialintermediaries. (4) For stockmarkettradingas apercentage of GDP,Taiwanis omitted because its trading/GDPratioin 1990 was almostten times largerthanthe nexthighest trading/GDPratio(Singapore).WithTaiwan included, the middle-income stocktradingratiobecomes 37.3 percent. country work in this area. He traced the relationship between the mix of financial intermediaries and economic development for 35 countries over the period 1860-1963. The World Bank (1989) and Demirgu,-Kunt and Levine (1996b) recently extended Goldsmith's work by examining the association between the mix of financial intermediaries, markets, and economic development for approximately 50 countries over the period 1970-1993. This work finds that financial structure differs considerably across countries and changes as countries develop economically. Four basic findings emerge from these studies, which are illustrated in Figure 2. As countries get richer over This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 717 time or as one shifts from poor to richer countries, (1) financial intermediaries get larger as measured by the total assets or liabilities of financial intermediaries relative to GDP; (2) banks grow relative to the central bank in allocating credit; (3) non-banks-such as insurance companies, investment banks, finance companies, and private pension funds-grow in importance; and (4) stock markets become larger, as measured by market capitalization relative to GDP, and more liquid, as measured by trading relative to GDP, market capitalization, and stock price variability. While these "patterns" pose a challenge to financial theorists, they must be treated cautiously because the data suffer from numerous problems. For example, it is difficult to distinguish private from public banks and development banks from commercial banks in many countries. Similarly, the definition of a bank and of a non-bank are not always consistent across countries. Furthermore, there is nothing causal about these relationships. These patterns alone do not suggest that poor countries can accelerate their growth rates by changing the structure of their financial systems. Finally, many differences exist across countries at similar stages of economic development (World Bank 1989). For example, the assets of deposit banks composed 56 percent of financial system assets in France, while the comparable number in the United Kingdom was 35 percent. The assets of contractual savings institutions composed 26 percent of total financial system assets in the United Kingdom, while in France the figure was only 7 percent in 1985. Thus, while there is a general trend involving financial structure and the level of GDP per capita, there are important exceptions and differences within income groups. While one must be hesitant in drawing conclusions about patterns of financial development, an even greater degree of hesitancy is called for in linking financial structure to economic growth. G. Financial Structureand Economic Growth There exists considerable debate, with sparse evidence and insufficient theory, about the relationship between financial structure and economic growth. After briefly outlining the major examples used in discussions of financial structure, I describe the major analytical limitations impeding research on financial structure and economic growth. The classic controversy involves the comparison between Germany and the United Kingdom. Starting early in this century, economists argued that differences in the financial structure of the two countries help explain Germany's more rapid economic growth rate during the latter half of the 19th century and the first decade of the 20th century (Alexander Gerschenkron 1962). The premise is as follows. Germany's bank-based financial system, where banks have close ties to industry, reduces the costs of acquiring information about firms. This makes it easier for the financial system to identify good investments, exert corporate control, and mobilize savings for promising investments than in England's more securities market oriented financial system, where the ties between banks and industry are less intimate. Indeed, quite a bit of evidence suggests that German bankers were more closely tied to industry than British bankers. Unlike England, nearly all German bankers started as merchants. The evolution from entrepreneur to banker may explain the comThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 718 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) paratively close bonds between bankers and industrialists. For example, German bankers frequently "mappedout a firm's paths of growth, conceived farsighted plans, decided on majortechnological innovations, and arrangedfor mergers and capital increases" (Gerschenkron 1968, p. 137). Private German bankers also organized and promoted an impressive array of major manufacturing companies during the mid-19th century (Richard Tilly 1967, p. 179). Besides this entrepreneurial role, some evidence suggests that German bankers tended to be more committed to the long-term funding of their clients than English bankers. Short-term credits could be transformed into longer-term securities more easily in Germany (Tilly 1967, pp. 178-81). Thus, various pieces of evidence suggest a closer relationship between banker and industrialist in Germany. While bankindustry relationships may have been closer in Germany, this does not imply that the German financial system was better at risk management, providing liquidity, or facilitating exchange. Furthermore, economists disagree over whether the growth differential between the two was really very large. Although German manufacturingproduction grew noticeably faster than Britain'sin the six decades before World War I, Germany's overall per capita GNP growth rate was 1.55 while the U.K.'s was 1.35 over the period 1850 to 1913 (Goldsmith 1969, pp. 406-07). Thus, aggregate growth differences are not very large, the significant differences that do exist are industry specific, and other factors besides differences in financial structure may explain industry specific growth differentials over this period. The debate concerning bank-based versus market-based systems eventually expanded to include comparisons with the United States. German banks are larger as a share of GDP than U.S. banks and Germanbankers tend to be more intricately involved in the management of industry than U.S. bankers (Randall Pozdena and Volbert Alexander 1992; Franklin Allen and Gale 1995; and Demirgu,-Kunt and Levine 1996a). Furthermore, historical evidence suggests that German universal banks were more efficient (lower cost of capital) than U.S. banks over the 1870-1914 period and suffered less systemic problems than the U.S. bankingsystem (Calomiris 1995). In contrast, the U.S. financial system is typically characterized as having a comparatively larger, more active securities markets with more equities held by households. These observations suggest that the German bank-based system may reduce information asymmetries and thereby allow banks to allocate capital more efficiently and to exert corporate control more effectively. In contrast, the United States' securities market-based financial system may offer advantagesin terms of boosting risk sharingopportunities (Allen and Gale 1995). While this functional approach highlights the relevant issues, substantially more research is needed before drawing conclusions about the dominance of one financial structure over another.30 Many of the arguments involving bank-based versus securities marketbased financial systems have been used to compare Japanand the United States. For example, research suggests that Japanese bankers are more closely tied to industrial clients than U.S. bankers. This closer connection may mitigate information asymmetries (Hoshi, Kasyap, and Sharfstein 1990), which may foster better investment and faster growth. Thus, the structure of the Japanese financial system is sometimes viewed as superior to the financial structure of the 30 Park (1993) compares the structure and functioning of the financial systems of Korea and Taiwan in relation to their industrialcomposition. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 719 United States and an important factor in Japan's faster growth rate over the last four decades. Interestingly, however, the recent banking problems and slower growth in Japan have led some to argue that the absence of a credible takeover threat through efficient stock markets has impeded proper corporate governance and competitiveness. These conflicting analyses highlight the need for better empirical measures of financial structure and the functions provided by financial systems. There are severe analytical problems with linking financial structure to economic performance. First, existing research on financial structure does not quantify the structure of financial systems or how well different financial systems function overall. For example, German bankers may have been more closely connected to industrialists than their British counterparts, but less capable at providing liquidity and facilitating transactions. Similarly, while Japanese Keiretsu may lower information acquisition costs between banks and firms, this does not necessarily imply that the Japanese financial system provides greater risk sharing mechanisms or more accurately spot promising new lines of business. Furthermore, while Japan is sometimes viewed as a bank-based system, it has one of the best developed stock markets in the world (Demirgu,-Kunt and Levine 1996a). Thus, the lack of quantitative measures of financial structure and the functioning of financial systems make it difficult to compare financial structures. Second, given the array of factors influencing growth in Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States, it is analytically difficult-and perhaps reckless-to attribute differences in growth rates to differences in the financial sector. Moreover, over the post World War II period, the devastated Axis powers may simply have been converging to the income levels of the United States, such that observed growth rate differentials have little to do with financial structure. Thus, before linking financial structure with economic growth, researchers need to control for other factors influencing long-run growth. A third factor that complicates the analysis of financial structure and economic growth is more fundamental. The current debate focuses on bank-based systems versus market-based systems. Some aggregate and firm level evidence, however, suggest that this dichotomy is inappropriate. The data indicate that both stock market liquidity-as measured by stock trading relative to GDP and market capitalization-and the level of banking development-as measured by bank credits to private firms divided by GDP predict economic growth over subsequent decades (Levine and Zervos 1996). Thus, it is not banks or stock markets; bank and stock market development indicators both predict economic growth. Perhaps, the debate should not focus on bank-based versus marketbased systems because these two components of the financial system enter the growth regression significantly and predict future economic growth. It may be that stock markets provide a different bundle of financial functions from those provided by financial intermediaries. For example, stock markets may primarily offer vehicles for trading risk and boosting liquidity. In contrast, banks may focus on ameliorating information acquisition costs and enhancing corporate governance of major corporations. This is merely a conjecture, however. There are important overlaps between the services provided by banks and stock markets. As noted above, well-functioning stock markets may ameliorate information acquisition costs, and banks may This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 720 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) provide instruments for diversifying risk and enhancing liquidity. Thus, to understand the relationship between financial structure and economic growth, we need theories of the simultaneous emergence of stock markets and banks and we need empirical proxies of the functions performed by the different components of financialsystems. A fourth factor limiting our understanding of the links between financial structure and economic growth is that researchers have focused on a few industrialized countries due to data limitations. The United States, Germany, Japan, and the United Kingdom have basically the same standardof living. Averaged over a sufficiently long time period, they must also have very similar growth rates. Thus, comparisons of financial structure and economic development using only these countries will tend to suggest that financial structure is unrelated to the level and growth rate of economic development. Future studies will need to incorporate a more diverse selection of countries to have even a chance of identifying patterns between financial structure and economic devel- opment. Finally, there are important interactions between stock markets and banks during economic development that have not been the focus of bank-based versus market-based comparisons. As noted, greater stock market liquidity is associated with faster rates of capital formation. Nonetheless, new equity sales do not finance much of this new investment (Colin Mayer 1988), though important differences exist across countries (Ajit Singh and Javed Hamid 1992). Most new corporate investment is financed by retained earnings and debt. This raises a quandary: stock market liquidity is positively associated with investment, but equity sales do not finance much of this investment. This quandary is confirmed by firm-level studies. In relatively poor countries, enhanced stock market liquidity actually tends to boost corporate debt-equity ratios; stock market liquidity does not induce a substitution out of debt and into equity finance (Demirgu,-Kunt and Maksimovic1996a). However, for industrialized countries, debt-equity ratios fall as stock market liquidity rises; stock market liquidity induces a substitution out of debt finance. The evidence suggests complex interactions between the functioning of stock markets and corporate decisions to borrow from banksthat depend on the overall level of economic development. Thus, we need considerably more research into the links among stock markets, banks, and corporate financing decisions to understand the relationship between financial structure and economic growth. IV. Conclusions Since Goldsmith (1969) documented the relationship between financial and economic development 30 years ago, the profession has made important progress. Rigorous theoretical work carefully illuminates many of the channels through which the emergence of financial markets and institutions affect-and are affected by-economic development. A growing body of empirical analyses, including firm-level studies, industry-level studies, individual country-studies, and broad cross country comparisons, demonstrate a strong positive link between the functioning of the financial system and long-run economic growth. Theory and evidence make it difficult to conclude that the financial system merelyand automatically-responds to industrialization and economic activity, or that financial development is an inconsequential addendum to the process of economic growth. I believe that we will This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 721 not have a sufficient understanding of long-run economic growth until we understand the evolution and functioning of financial systems. This conclusion about financial development and longrun growth has an important corollary: although financial panics and recessions are critical issues, the finance-growth link goes beyond the relationship between finance and shorter-term fluctua- tions. Undoubtedly, the financial system is shaped by nonfinancial developments. Changes in telecommunications, computers, nonfinancial sector policies, institutions, and economic growth itself influence the quality of financial services and the structure of the financial system. Technological improvements lower transaction costs and affect financial arrangements (Merton 1992). Monetary and fiscal policies affect the taxation of financial intermediaries and the provision of financial services (Bencivenga and B. Smith 1992; Roubini and Sala-iMartin 1995). Legal systems affect financial systems (LaPorta et al. 1996), and political changes and national institutions critically influence financial development (Haber 1991, 1996). Furthermore, economic growth alters the willingness of savers and investors to pay the costs associated with participating in the financial system (Greenwood and Jovanovic 1990). While economists have made important advances, we need much more research on financial development. Why does financial structure change as countries grow?Why do countries at similar stages of economic development have different looking financial systems? Are there long-run economic growth advantages to adopting legal and policy changes that create one type of financial structure vis-a-vis another? Much more information about the determinants and implications of financial structure will move us closer to a comprehensive view of financial development and economic growth. REFERENCES AGHION, PHILIPPE AND HOWITT, PETER. "A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction," Econometrica, Mar. 1992, 60(2), pp. 323- 51. ALLEN, FRANKLIN AND GALE, DOUGLAS. "A Welfare Comparison of Intermediaries and Financial Markets in Germany and the Us," Europ. Econ. Rev., Feb. 1995, 39(2), pp. 179- 209. AMIHUD, YAKOV AND MENDELSON, HAIM. "The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk, and Size on Stock Returns," J. Finance, June 1989, 44(2), pp. 479-86. ARESTIS, PHILIP AND DEMETRIADES, PANICOS. "'Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right' A Comment on King and Levine." U. of East London mimeo, 1995. ARROW, KENNETH J. "The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bearing," Rev. Econ. Stud., Apr. 1964, (2), pp. 91-96. ATJE, RAYMOND AND JOVANOVIC, BOYAN. "Stock Marketsand Development," Europ. Econ. Rev., Apr. 1993, 37(2/3), pp. 632-40. BAGEHOT, WALTER. Lombardstreet. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, [1873] 1962 Edition. BENCIVENGA, VALERIE R. AND SMITH, BRUCE D. "Financial Intermediation and Endogenous Growth," Rev. Econ. Stud., Apr. 1991, 58(2), pp. 195-209. . "Deficits, Inflation, and the Banking System in Developing Countries: The Optimal Degree of Financial Repression," Oxford Econ. Pap., Oct. 1992, 44(4), pp. 767-90. . "Some Consequences of Credit Rationing in an Endogenous GrowthModel,"J.Econ. Dynam. Control, Jan.-Mar. 1993, 17(1/2), pp. 97- 122. BENCIVENGA, VALERIE R.; SMITH, BRUCE D. AND STARR, Ross M. "Transactions Costs, Technological Choice, and Endogenous Growth,"J.Econ. Theory, Oct. 1995, 67(1), PP. 153-77. BENNETT, ROBERT L. "FinancialInnovation and Structural Change in the Early Stages of Industrialization:Mexico, 1945-59," J.Finance, Dec. 1963, 18(4), pp. 666-83. BERGER, ALLEN N. AND UDELL, GREGORY F. "Relationship Lending and Lines of Credit in Small Firm Finance,"J. Bus., July 1995, 68(3), pp. 351-81. BERNANKE, BEN AND GERTLER, MARK. "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations," Amer.Econ. Rev., Mar.1989, 79(1), pp. 14-. . "Financial Fragility and Economic Performance," Quart. J. Econ., Feb. 1990, 105(1), pp. 87-114. BERTHELEMY, JEAN-CLAUDE AND VAROUDAKIS, ARISTOMENE. "Economic Growth, Convergence Clubs, and the Role of Financial DevelThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 722 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) opment," Oxford Econ. Pap., Apr. 1996, 48(2), pp. 300-28. BHIDE, AMAR. "The Hidden Costs of Stock Market Liquidity," J. Finan. Econ., Aug. 1993, 34(1), pp. -51. BOYD, JOHN H. AND PRESCOTT, EDWARD C. "Financial Intermediary-Coalitions," J. Econ. Theory, Apr. 1986, 38(2), pp. 211-32. BOYD, JOHN H. AND SMITH, BRUCE D. "How Good Are Standard Debt Contracts? Stochastic Versus Nonstochastic Monitoring in a Costly State Verification Environment," J. Bus., Oct. 1994, 67(4), pp. 539-61. . "The Co-Evolution of the Real and Financial Sectors in the Growth Process," World BankEcon. Rev., May 1996,10(2), pp. 371-96. BROCK, PHILIP L., ed. If Texas were Chile: A primer on banking reform. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press, 1992. BRUNNER, KARL AND MELTZER, ALLEN H. "The Uses of Money: Money in the Theory of an Exchange Economy," Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. 1971, 61(5), pp. 784-805. CALOMIRIS, CHARLES W. "The Costs of Rejecting Universal Banking: American Finance in the German Mirror, 1870-1914," in Coordination and information:Historical perspectives on the organization of enterprise. Eds.: NAOMI R. LAMOREAUX AND DANIEL M. G. RAFF. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1995, pp. 257-321. CALOMIRIS, CHARLES W.; HIMMELBERG, CHARLES P. AND WACHTEL, PAUL. "Commercial Paper, Corporate Finance, and the Business Cycle: A Microeconomic Perspective," Carnegie-Rochester Confer. Ser. Pub. Policy, June 1995, 42, pp. 203-50. CALOMIRIS, CHARLES W. AND HUBBARD, R. GLENN. "Internal Finance and Investment: Evidence from the Undistributed Profits Tax of 1936-37,"J. Bus., Oct. 1995, 68(4), pp. 443-82. CAMERON, RONDO. "Scotland, 1750-1845," 1967a in RONDO CAMERON ET AL. 1967, pp. 60-99. . "Conclusion," 1967b in RONDO CAMERON ET AL. 1967, pp. 290-321. CAMERON, RONDO ET AL. Banking in the early stages of undustrialization:A study in comparative economic history. New York: Oxford U. Press, 1967. CAPRIO, GERARD, JR.; ATIYAS, IZAK AND HANSON, JAMES A. Financial reform:Theoryand experience. New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1994. CAROSSO, VINCENT. Investment banking in America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1970. CHANDAVARKAR, ANAND. "Of Finance and Development: Neglected and Unsettled Questions," World Devel., Jan. 1992, 20(1), pp. 133-42. CHECKLAND, SYDNEY G. Scottish banking:A history, 1695-1973. Glasgow: Collins, 1975. COLE, DAVID C. AND PARK, YUNG CHUL. Financial development of Korea 1945-1978. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1983. COLE, DAVID C. AND SLADE, BETTY F. "Reform of Financial Systems," in Reforming economic systems in developing countries. Eds.: DWIGHT PERKINS AND MICHAEL ROEMER. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1991, pp. 3-40. COOLEY, THOMAS F. AND SMITH, BRUCE D. "Financial Markets, Specialization, and Learning by Doing." Cornell U. mimeo, 1992. COWEN, TYLER AND KROSZNER, RANDALL. "Scottish Banking Before 1845: A Model for LaissezFaire?"J. Money, Credit, Banking, May 1989, 21(2), p. 221-. DAVIS, LANCE E. AND HUTTENBACK, ROBERT A. Mammonand the pursuit of empire: The political economyof British imperlialism, 1869-1912. Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1986. DEBREU, GERARD. Theory of value. New York: Wiley, 1959. DE GREGORIO, JOSE. "Borrowing Constraints, Human Capital Accumulation, and Growth," J. Monet.Econ., Feb. 1996, 37(1), pp. 49-71. DE LONG, J. BRADFORD. "Did J. P. Morgan's Men Add Value? An Economist's Perspective on Financial Capitalism,"in Inside the business enterprise: Historical perspectives on the use of information. Ed. PETER TEMIN. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1991, pp. 205-36. DE LONG, J. BRADFORD ET AL. "The Size and Incidence of the Losses from Noise Trading," J. Finance, July 1989, 44(3), pp. 681-96. DEMIRGUCS-KUNT, ASLI AND LEVINE, Ross. "Stock Market Development and Financial Intermediaries: Stylized Facts," World Bank Econ. Rev., May1996a, 10(2), 291-322. . "Stock Markets, Corporate Finance, and Economic Growth: An Overview," World Bank Econ. Rev., May1996b, 10(2), 223-40. DEMIRGUCS-KUNT, ASLI AND MAKSIMOVIC, VOJISLAV. "Stock Market Development and Financing Choices of Firms," World Bank Econ. Rev., May1996a 10(2), pp. 341-70. . "Financial Constraints, Uses of Funds, and Firm Growth: An International Comparison." World Bank mimeo, 1996b. DEVEREUX, MICHAEL B. AND SMITH, GREGOR W. "International Risk Sharing and Economic Growth," Int. Econ. Rev., Aug. 1994, 35(4), pp. 535-50. DIAMOND, DOUGLAS W. "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring," Rev. Econ. Stud., July 1984, 51(3), pp. 393-414. DIAMOND, DOUGLAS W. AND DYBVIG, PHILIP H. "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity," J.Polit. Econ., June 1983, 91(3), pp. 401-19. DIAMOND, DOUGLAS W. AND VERRECCHIA, ROBERTE. "Optimal Managerial Contracts and Equilibrium Security Prices," J. Finance, May 1982, 37, pp. 275-87. EASTERLY,WILLIAM. "How Much Do Distortions Affect Growth?"J. Monet. Econ., Nov. 1993, 32(4), p. 187-212, ENGERMAN, STANLEY L. AND SOKOLOFF, KENNETH L. "Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States," in How Latin This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 723 America fell behind. Ed.: STEPHEN HABER. Stanford, CA: Stanford U. Press, 1996, pp. 260- 304. FAZZARI, STEVEN M.; HUBBARD, R. GLENN AND PETERSEN, BRUCE C. "Financing Constraints, and Investment,"Brookings Pap. Econ. Act., Aug. 1988, 1, pp. 141-206. FRY, MAXWELL J. Money, interest, and banking in economic development. Baltimore: John Hopkins U. Press, 1995. GALE, DOUGLAS AND HELLWIG, MARTIN. "Incentive-Compatible Debt Contracts: The OnePeriod Prob em," Rev. Econ. Stud., Oct. 1985, 52(4), pp. 647-63. GELB, ALAN H. "Financial Policies, Growth, and Efficiency." World Bank PPR Working Paper No. 202, June 1989. GERSCHENKRON, ALEXANDER. Economic backwardness in historical perspective-A book of essays. Cambridge: Harvard U. Press, 1962. . Continuity in history and other essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1968. GERTLER, MARK. "Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview," J. Money, Credit, Banking, Aug. 1988, 20(3, Pt. 2), pp. 559-88. GERTLER, MARK AND GILCHRIST, SIMON. "Monetary Policy, Business Cycles, and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing Firms," Quart. J. Econ., May1994, 109(2), pp. 309-40. GERTLER, MARK AND ROSE, ANDREW. "Finance, Public Policy and Growth," in GERARD CAPRIO, JR., IZAK ATILJAS, AND JAMES A. HANSON. 1994, pp. 13-45. GIOVANNINI, ALBERTO AND DE MELO, MARTHA. "Government Revenue from Financial Repression," Amer. Econ. Rev.., Sept. 1993, 83(4), pp. 953-63. GOLDSMITH, RAYMOND, W. Financial structure and development. New Haven, CT: Yale U. Press, 1969. GORTON, GARY AND PENNACCHI, GEORGE. "Financial Intermediaries and Liquidity Creation," J.Finance, Mar. 1990, 45(1), pp. 49-71. GREENWOOD, JEREMY AND JOVANOVIC, BOYAN. "Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution of Income," J.Polit. Econ., Oct. 1990, 98(5,Pt.1), pp. 1076-1107. GREENWOOD, JEREMY AND SMITH, BRUCE. "Financial Markets in Development, and the Development of Financial Markets," J. Econ. Dynamics and Control, Jan. 1997, 21(1), pp. 145-81. GROSSMAN, GENE M. AND HELPMAN, ELHANAN. "Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth," Rev. Econ. Stud., Jan. 1991, 58(1), pp. 43-61. GROSSMAN, SANFORD J. AND MILLER, MERTON H. "Liquidity and Market Structure," J. Finance, July 1988, 43(3), pp. 617-33. GROSSMAN, SANFORD J. AND STIGLITZ, JOSEPH E. "On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets," Amer. Econ. Rev., June 1980, 70(3), pp. 393-408. GUESLIN, ANDRE. "Banks and State in France from the 1880s to the 1930s: The Impossible Advance of the Banks," in Finance anN financiers in European history 1880-1960. Ed. YOUSSEF CASSIS. New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1992, pp. 63-92. GURLEY, JOHN G. AND SHAW, EDWARD S. "Financial Aspects of Economic Development," Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1955, 45(4), pp. 515- 38. HABER, STEPHEN H. "Industrial Concentration and the Capital Markets: A Comparative Study of Brazil, Mexico, and the United States, 1830- 1930,"J. Econ. Hist., Sept. 1991, 51(3), 559-80. - . "Capital Immobilities and Industrial Development: A Comparative Study of Brazil, Mexico, and the United States, 1840-1930." Stanford U. mimeo, 1996. HARRIS, JOHN R.; SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO AND SIREGAR,MIRANDAG. "The Effect of Financial Liberalization on the Capital Structure and Investment Decisions of Indonesian Manufacturing Establishments," World Bank Econ. Rev., Jan. 1994, 8(1), pp. 17-47. HICKS, JOHN. A theory of economic history. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1969. HOLMSTROM, BENGT AND TIROLE, JEAN. "Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring," J. Polit. Econ., Aug. 1993,101(4), pp. 678-709. HOSHI, TAKEO; KASHYAP, ANIL K. AND SHARFSTEIN, DAVID S. "Bank Monitoring and Investment: Evidence from the Changing Structure of Japanese Corporate Banking Relationships," in Asymmetric information, corporate finance, and investment. Ed.: R.GLENN HUBBARD. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1990, pp. 105-26. HUBBARD, R. GLENN; KASHYAP, ANIL K. AND WHITED, TONI M. "International Finance and Firm Investment," J. Money Credit Banking, Aug. 1995, 27(3), pp. 683-701. INTERNATIONAL FINANCE CORPORATION. Emerging markets data base. Washington, DC: Various years. JACKLIN,CHARLESJ. "Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions, and Risk Sharing," in Contractual arrangements for intertemporal trade. Eds.: EDWARD D. PRESCOTT AND NEIL WALLACE. Minneapolis: U. of Minnesota Press, 1987, pp. 26-47. JAFFEE, DWIGHT M. AND RUSSELL, THOMAS. "Imperfect Information, Uncertainty, and Credit Rationing." Quart. J. Econ., Nov. 1976, 90(4), pp. 651-66. JAMES, CHRISTOPHER. "Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans,"J. Finan. Econ., Dec. 1987,19(2), pp. 217-36. JAMES, CHRISTOPHER AND WIER, PEGGY. "Borrowing Relationships, Intermediation, and the Cost of Issuing Public Securities," J. Finan. Econ., Nov.-Dec. 1990, 28(1/2), pp. 149-71. JAPPELLI, TULLIO AND PAGANO, MARCO. "Saving, Growth, and Liquidity Constraints," Quart. J. Econ., Feb. 1994, 109(1), pp. 83-109. JARAMILLO, FIDEL; SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO AND This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 724 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) WEISS, ANDREW. "Capital Market Imperfections, Financial Constraints and Investment: Econometric Evidence from Panel Data for Ecuador," J. Devel. Econ., Dec. 1996, 51(2), pp. 367-86. JAYARATNE, JITH AND STRAHAN, PHILIP E. "The Finance-Growth Nexus: Evidence from Bank Branch Deregulation," Quart. J. Econ., Aug. 1996, 111 (3), pp. 639-70. JENSEN, MICHAEL AND MECKLING, WILLIAM R. "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure," J. Finan. Econ., Oct. 1976, 3(4), pp. 305-60. JENSEN, MICHAEL C. AND MURPHY, KEVIN J. "Performance Pay and Top-Management Incentives, J. Polit. Econ., Apr. 1990, 98(2), pp. 225- 64. JEVONS, W. STANLEY. Money and the mechanism of exchange. London: Appleton, 1875. JUNG, WOO S. "Financial Development and Economic Growth: International Evidence," Econ. Devel. Cult. Change, Jan. 1986, 34(2), pp. 333- 46. KADLEC, GREGORY B. AND MCCONNELL, JOHN J. "The Effect of Market Segmentation and Illiquidity on Asset Prices: Evidence from Exchange Listings," J. Finance, June 1994, 49(2), pp. 611-36. KERR, ANDREW W. History of banking in Scotland. Glasgow, 1884; 3rd ed. London: A&C Black, 1918. KHAN, AUBHIK. "Financial Development and Economic Growth." U. of Virginia mimeo, 1994. KING, ROBERT G. AND LEVINE, Ross. "Financial Intermediation and Economic Development," in Financial intermediation in the construction of Europe. Eds.: COLIN MAYER AND XAVIER VIVES. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1993a, pp. 156-89. -. "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,"Quart.J.Econ., Aug. 1993b, 108(3), pp. 717-37. . "Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth: Theory and Evidence," J. Monet. Econ., Dec. 1993c, 32(3), pp. 513-42. KING, ROBERT G. AND PLOSSER, CHARLES I. "Money as the Mechanism of Exchange," J. Monet. Econ., Jan. 1986, 17(1), pp. 93-115. KRASA, STEFAN AND VILLAMIL, ANNE P. "Monitoring the Monitor: An Incentive Structure for a Financial Intermediary," J. Econ. Theory, June 1992, 57(1), pp. 197-221. KYLE, ALBERTS. "Market Structure, Information, Futures Markets, and Price Formation," in International agricultural trade: Advanced readings in price formation, market structure, and price instability. Eds.: GARY G. STOREY, ANDREW SCHMITZ, AND ALEXANDER H. SARRIS.Boulder, CO: Westview, 1984, pp. 45- 64. LAMOREAUX, NAOMI R. Insider lending: Banks, personal connections, and economic development in industrial New England, New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1994. LAMOREAUX, NAOMI AND SOKOLOFF, KENNETH L. "Long-Term Change in the Organization of Inventive Activity," Proceedingsof the National Academy of Science, Nov. 1996, 93, pp. 12686- 92. LAPORTA, RAFAEL ET AL. "Law and Finance." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5661. July 1996. LEVHARI, DAVID AND SRINIVASAN, T. N. "Optimal Savings Under Uncertainty," Rev. Econ. Stud., Apr. 1969, 36(1), pp. 153-63. LEVINE, Ross. "Stock Markets, Growth, and Tax Policy,"J.Finance, Sept. 1991, 46(4), pp. 1445- 65. . "Law, Finance, Economic Growth." U. of Virginia mimeo, 1997. LEVINE, Ross AND RENELT, DAVID. "A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,"Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1992, 82(4), pp. 942-63. LEVINE, Ross AND ZERVOS, SARA. "Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1690, Dec. 1996. LuCAS, ROBERT E., JR. "On the Mechanics of Economic Development," J. Monet. Econ., July 1988, 22(1), pp. 3-42. LUMMER, SCOTT L. AND MCCONNELL, JOHN J. "Further Evidence on the Bank Lending Process and the Capital Market Response to Bank Loan Agreements," J. Finan. Econ., Nov. 1989, 25(1), pp. 99-122. MAYER, COLIN. "New Issues in Corporate Finance," Europ. Econ. Rev., June 1988, 32(5), pp. 1167-83. MCKINNON, RONALD I. Moneyand capital in economic development. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1973. MEIER, GERALD M. AND SEERS, DUDLEY. Pioneers in development. New York: Oxford U. Press, 1984. MERTON, ROBERT C. "A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete In- formation,"J. Finance, July 1987, 42(3), pp. 483- 510. . "Financial Innovation and Economic Performance,"J. Applied Corporate Finance, Winter 1992, 4(4), pp. 12-22. MERTON, ROBERT C. AND BODIE, ZVI."AConceptual Framework for Analyzing the Financial Environment,"in Theglobalfinancial system:A functional perspective. Eds.: DWIGHT B. CRANE ET AL. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 1995, pp. 3-. MORCK, RANDALL; SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND VISHNY, ROBERT W. "Do Managerial Objectives Drive Bad Acquisitions?" J. Finance, Mar. 1990, 45(1), pp. -48 MYERS, STEWART C. AND MAJLUF, NICHOLAS S. "Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have," J. Finan. Econ., June 1984, 13(2), pp. 187-221. NEAL, LARRY. The rise offinancial capitalism:InThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Levine: Financial Development and Economic Growth 725 ternational capital marketsin the age of reason. New York:CambridgeU. Press, 1990. NEUSSER, KLAUS AND KUGLER, MAURICE. "ManufacturingGrowthand Financial Development: Evidence from OECD Countries." U. of Berne mimeo, 1996. NORTH, DOUGLASS C. Structure and change in economichistory. New York:Norton, 1981. OBSTFELD, MAURICE. "Risk-Taking, Global Diversification, and Growth,"Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. 1994, 84(5), pp. 10-29. OSTROY, JOSEPH M. AND STARR, Ross M. "The Transactions Role of Money," in, Handbook of monetary economics. Vol. 1. Eds.: BENJAMIN FRIEDMANAND FRANKH. HAHN. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1990, pp. 3-62. PAGANO, MARCO. "Financial Markets and Growth:An Overview,"Europ. Econ. Rev., Apr. 1993, 37(2-3), pp. 613-22. PARK,YUNG CHUL. "The Role of Finance in Economic Development in South Korea and Taiwan," in Finance and development: Issues and experience. Ed.: ALBERTO GIOVANNINI. Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, 1993, pp. 121-50. PATRICK,HUGH T. "Financial Development and Economic Growth in Underdeveloped Countries," Econ. Devel. Cult. Change, Jan. 1966, 14(2), pp. 174-89. PATRICK, HUGH T. AND PARK, YUNG CHUL. Financial development in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan. New York:OxfordU. Press, 1994. PENSO DE LA VEGA, JOSEF. Confusion de confusiones, 1688. Boston: Baker Library, Harvard Graduate School of Business, 1957. PETERSEN, MITCHELL A. AND RAJAN, RAGHURAM G. "The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from Small Business Data," J. Finance, Mar. 1994, 49(1), pp. 3-37. POLLARD, SIDNEY AND ZIEGLER, DIETER. "Banking and Industrialization: Rondo Cameron Twenty YearsOn,"in Finance andfinanciers in European history 1880-1960. Ed.: YOUSEF CASSIS. New York: Cambridge U. Press, 1992, pp. 17-38. POZDENA, RANDALL J.AND VOLBERT, ALEXANDER. "Bank Structure in West Germany," in Banking structures in major countries. Ed.: GEORGE G. KAUFMAN.Norwell, MA and Dordrecht: Kluwer,1992, pp. 555-90. RAJAN, RAGHURAMG. "Insiders and Outsiders: The Choice Between Informed and Armslength Debt,"J. Finance, Sept. 1992, 47(4), pp. 1367- 1400. RAJAN, RAGHURAM G. AND ZINGALES, LUIGI. "Financial Dependence and Growth." U. of Chicago mimeo, May 1996. REBELO, SERGIO T. "Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth,"J. Polit. Econ., June 1991, 99(3), pp. 500-21. ROBINSON, JOAN. "The Generalization of the General Theory," in The rate of interest, and other essays. London: Macmillan,1952, pp. 67- 142. ROMER, PAUL M. "Increasing Returns and LongRun Growth,"J.Polit. Econ., Oct. 1986, 94(5), pp.1002-37. . "Endogenous Technological Change," J. Polit. Econ., Oct. 1990, 98(5, Pt. 2), pp. S71- 102. ROUBINI, NOURIEL AND SALA-I-MARTIN, XAVIER. "Financial Repression and Economic Growth,"J.Devel. Econ., July 1992, 39(1), pp. 5-30. . "A Growth Model of Inflation, Tax Evasion, and Financial Repression," J. Monet. Econ., Apr. 1995, 35(2), pp. 275-301. SAINT-PAUL, GILLES. "Technological Choice, Financial Markets and Economic Development," Europ. Econ. Rev., May 1992, 36(4), pp. 763- 81. SCHARFSTEIN, DAVID. "The Disciplinary Role of Takeovers,"Rev. Econ. Stud., Apr. 1988, 55(2), pp. 185-99. SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO. "Financial Constraints and Investment: A Critical Rev. Methodological Issues and International Evidence," in Is bank lending importantfor the transmissionof monetary policy? Eds.: JOE PEEK AND ERIC S. ROSENGREN. Boston, MA: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series No. 39, June 1995, pp. 177-214. SCHIANTARELLI, FABIO AND SEMBENELLI, ALESSANDRO. "Form of Ownership and Financial Constraints: Panel Data Evidence From Leverage and Investment Equations." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1629, 1996. SCHUMPETER, JOSEPH A. Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung [The theory of economic development].Leipzig: Dunker & Humblot, 1912; translated by REDVERS OPIE. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press, 1934. SHARPE, STEVEN A. "Asymmetric Information, Bank Lending, and Implicit Contracts: A Stylized Model of Customer Relationships," J. Finance, Sept. 1990, 45(4), pp. 1069-87. SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND SUMMERS, LAWRENCE H. "Breach of Trust in Hostile Takeovers," in Corporatetakeovers: Causes and consequences. Ed.: ALAN J. AUERBACH. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1988, pp. 33-56. SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND VISHY, ROBERT W. "Large Shareholders and Corporate Control," J. Polit. Econ., June 1986, 94(3), pp. 461-88. -. "A Survey of Corporate Governance," J. Finance, forthcoming. SINGH, AJIT AND HAMID, JAVED. "Corporate Financial Structures in Developing Countries." Washington, DC: International Finance Corporation Technical Paper 1, 1992. SIRRI, ERIK R. AND TUFANO, PETER. "The Economics of Pooling," in The global financial system:Afunctional perspective. Eds.: DWIGHT B. CRANE ET AL. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press, 1995, pp. 81-128. SLOVIN, MYRON B.; SUSHKA, MARIE E. AND POLONCHEK, JOHN A. "The Value of Bank DuThis content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 726 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV(June 1997) rability:Borrowersas Bank Stakeholders,"J. Finance, Mar.1993, 48(1), pp. 247-66. SMITH, ADAM. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London:W. Stahan &T. Cadell, 1776. STEIN, JEREMY C. "TakeoverThreats and Managerial Myopia,"J. Polit. Econ., Feb. 1988, 96(1), pp. 61-80. STERN, NICHOLAS. "The Economics of Development: A Survey,"Econ. J., Sept. 1989, 99(397), pp. 597-685. STIGLITZ, JOSEPH E. "Credit Markets and the Control of Capital,"J. Money, Credit, Banking, May 1985,17(2), pp. 133-52. STIGLITZ, JOSEPH E. AND WEISS, ANDREW. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information," Amer. Econ. Rev., June 1981, 71(3), pp. 393-410. -. "Incentive Effects of Terminations:Applications to Credit and Labor Markets,"Amer. Econ. Rev., Dec. 1983, 73(5), pp. 912-27. VON THADDEN, ERNST-LUDWIG. "Long-Term Contracts, Short-Term Investment and Monitoring,"Rev. Econ. Stud., Oct. 1995, 62(4), pp. 557-75. TILLY, RICHARD. "Germany, 1815-1870," in Banking in the early stages of industrialization: A study in comparative economic history. Eds.: RONDO CAMERON ET AL. New York:OxfordU. Press, 1967, pp. 151-82. TOBIN, JAMES. "Money and Economic Growth", Econometrica,Oct. 1965, 33(4), Pp.671-84. TOWNSEND, ROBERT M. "OptimalContracts and Competitive Marketswith Costly State Verification," J. Econ. Theory, Oct. 1979, 21(2), pp. 265-93. TYBOUT, JAMES R. "Credit Rationing and Investment Behavior in a Developing Country,"Rev. Econ. Statist., Nov. 1983, 65(4), pp. 598-607. WACHTEL, PAUL AND ROUSSEAU, PETER. "Financial Intermediation and Economic Growth: A Historical Comparison of the U.S., U.K., and Canada,"in Anglo-Americanfinancial systems: Institutions and markets in twentieth-century North America and the United Kingdom. Eds.: MICHAEL D. BORDO AND RICHARD SYLLA. Homewood, IL: Business One Irwin, 1995, pp. 329-82. WELLS, STEPHEN. "TurnoverStatistics and Trade Reporting,"London Stock Exchange Quarterly witl Quality of MarketsRev., Spring 1994, pp. 23-26. WHITED, TONI M. "Debt, Liquidity Constraints, and Corporate Investment: Evidence from Panel Data,"J. Finance, Sept. 1992, 47(4), pp. 1425-60. WILLIAMSON, STEPHEN D. "Costly Monitoring, Financial Intermediation, and Equilibrium Credit Rationing,"J. Monet. Econ., Sept. 1986, 18(2), pp. 159-79. . "Costly Monitoring, Loan Contracts, and Equilibrium Credit Rationing,"Quart.J. Econ., Feb. 1987a, 102(1), pp. 135-45. - . "Financial Intermediation, Business Failures, and Real Business Cycles,"J. Polit. Econ., Dec. 1987b, 95(6), pp. 1196-1216. WILLIAMSON, STEVE AND WRIGHT, RANDALL. "Barterand Monetary Exchange Under Private Information," Amer. Econ. Rev., Mar. 1994, 84(1), pp. 104-23. WORLD BANK. World development report Washington, DC: OxfordU. Press, 1989. This content downloaded from 147.251.194.197 on Sun, 15 Sep 2013 08:53:55 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions