microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. microtitle.jpg microedition.jpg varianname.jpg 21 Cost Curves microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Types of Cost Curves uA total cost curve is the graph of a firm’s total cost function. uA variable cost curve is the graph of a firm’s variable cost function. uAn average total cost curve is the graph of a firm’s average total cost function. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Types of Cost Curves uAn average variable cost curve is the graph of a firm’s average variable cost function. uAn average fixed cost curve is the graph of a firm’s average fixed cost function. uA marginal cost curve is the graph of a firm’s marginal cost function. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Types of Cost Curves uHow are these cost curves related to each other? uHow are a firm’s long-run and short-run cost curves related? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed, Variable & Total Cost Functions uF is the total cost to a firm of its short-run fixed inputs. F, the firm’s fixed cost, does not vary with the firm’s output level. ucv(y) is the total cost to a firm of its variable inputs when producing y output units. cv(y) is the firm’s variable cost function. ucv(y) depends upon the levels of the fixed inputs. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Fixed, Variable & Total Cost Functions uc(y) is the total cost of all inputs, fixed and variable, when producing y output units. c(y) is the firm’s total cost function; microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $ F microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $ cv(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $ F cv(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $ F cv(y) c(y) F microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Av. Fixed, Av. Variable & Av. Total Cost Curves uThe firm’s total cost function is For y > 0, the firm’s average total cost function is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Av. Fixed, Av. Variable & Av. Total Cost Curves uWhat does an average fixed cost curve look like? uAFC(y) is a rectangular hyperbola so its graph looks like ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) y 0 AFC(y) ® 0 as y ® ¥ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Av. Fixed, Av. Variable & Av. Total Cost Curves uIn a short-run with a fixed amount of at least one input, the Law of Diminishing (Marginal) Returns must apply, causing the firm’s average variable cost of production to increase eventually. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AVC(y) y 0 microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) AVC(y) y 0 microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Av. Fixed, Av. Variable & Av. Total Cost Curves uAnd ATC(y) = AFC(y) + AVC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) AVC(y) ATC(y) y 0 ATC(y) = AFC(y) + AVC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) AVC(y) ATC(y) y 0 AFC(y) = ATC(y) - AVC(y) AFC microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) AVC(y) ATC(y) y 0 Since AFC(y) ® 0 as y ® ¥, ATC(y) ® AVC(y) as y ® ¥. AFC microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit AFC(y) AVC(y) ATC(y) y 0 Since AFC(y) ® 0 as y ® ¥, ATC(y) ® AVC(y) as y ® ¥. And since short-run AVC(y) must eventually increase, ATC(y) must eventually increase in a short-run. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Cost Function uMarginal cost is the rate-of-change of variable production cost as the output level changes. That is, microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal Cost Function uThe firm’s total cost function is and the fixed cost F does not change with the output level y, so uMC is the slope of both the variable cost and the total cost functions. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal and Variable Cost Functions uSince MC(y) is the derivative of cv(y), cv(y) must be the integral of MC(y). That is, microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal and Variable Cost Functions MC(y) y 0 Area is the variable cost of making y’ units $/output unit microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions uHow is marginal cost related to average variable cost? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Since microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Since Therefore, as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Since Therefore, as as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) The short-run MC curve intersects the short-run AVC curve from below at the AVC curve’s minimum. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Similarly, since microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Similarly, since Therefore, as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions Similarly, since Therefore, as as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y MC(y) ATC(y) as microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Marginal & Average Cost Functions uThe short-run MC curve intersects the short-run AVC curve from below at the AVC curve’s minimum. uAnd, similarly, the short-run MC curve intersects the short-run ATC curve from below at the ATC curve’s minimum. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $/output unit y AVC(y) MC(y) ATC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves uA firm has a different short-run total cost curve for each possible short-run circumstance. uSuppose the firm can be in one of just three short-runs; x2 = x2¢ or x2 = x2¢¢ x2¢ < x2¢¢ < x2¢¢¢. or x2 = x2¢¢¢. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y 0 F¢ = w2x2¢ F¢ cs(y;x2¢) $ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢ = w2x2¢ F¢¢ F¢¢ = w2x2¢¢ cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢ = w2x2¢ F¢¢ = w2x2¢¢ A larger amount of the fixed input increases the firm’s fixed cost. cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢ = w2x2¢ F¢¢ = w2x2¢¢ A larger amount of the fixed input increases the firm’s fixed cost. Why does a larger amount of the fixed input reduce the slope of the firm’s total cost curve? cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› MP1 is the marginal physical productivity of the variable input 1, so one extra unit of input 1 gives MP1 extra output units. Therefore, the extra amount of input 1 needed for 1 extra output unit is Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› MP1 is the marginal physical productivity of the variable input 1, so one extra unit of input 1 gives MP1 extra output units. Therefore, the extra amount of input 1 needed for 1 extra output unit is Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves units of input 1. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› MP1 is the marginal physical productivity of the variable input 1, so one extra unit of input 1 gives MP1 extra output units. Therefore, the extra amount of input 1 needed for 1 extra output unit is Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves units of input 1. Each unit of input 1 costs w1, so the firm’s extra cost from producing one extra unit of output is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› MP1 is the marginal physical productivity of the variable input 1, so one extra unit of input 1 gives MP1 extra output units. Therefore, the extra amount of input 1 needed for 1 extra output unit is Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves units of input 1. Each unit of input 1 costs w1, so the firm’s extra cost from producing one extra unit of output is microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves is the slope of the firm’s total cost curve. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves is the slope of the firm’s total cost curve. If input 2 is a complement to input 1 then MP1 is higher for higher x2. Hence, MC is lower for higher x2. That is, a short-run total cost curve starts higher and has a lower slope if x2 is larger. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢ = w2x2¢ F¢¢ = w2x2¢¢ F¢¢¢ F¢¢¢ = w2x2¢¢¢ cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves uThe firm has three short-run total cost curves. uIn the long-run the firm is free to choose amongst these three since it is free to select x2 equal to any of x2¢, x2¢¢, or x2¢¢¢. uHow does the firm make this choice? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = ? cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. For y¢ £ y £ y¢¢, choose x2 = ? cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. For y¢ £ y £ y¢¢, choose x2 = x2¢¢. cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. For y¢ £ y £ y¢¢, choose x2 = x2¢¢. For y¢¢ < y, choose x2 = ? cs(y;x2¢¢¢) cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ cs(y;x2¢¢¢) y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. For y¢ £ y £ y¢¢, choose x2 = x2¢¢. For y¢¢ < y, choose x2 = x2¢¢¢. cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y F¢ 0 cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) F¢¢¢ cs(y;x2¢¢¢) y¢ y¢¢ For 0 £ y £ y¢, choose x2 = x2¢. For y¢ £ y £ y¢¢, choose x2 = x2¢¢. For y¢¢ < y, choose x2 = x2¢¢¢. c(y), the firm’s long- run total cost curve. $ F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves uThe firm’s long-run total cost curve consists of the lowest parts of the short-run total cost curves. The long-run total cost curve is the lower envelope of the short-run total cost curves. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Total Cost Curves uIf input 2 is available in continuous amounts then there is an infinity of short-run total cost curves but the long-run total cost curve is still the lower envelope of all of the short-run total cost curves. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› $ y F¢ 0 F¢¢¢ cs(y;x2¢) cs(y;x2¢¢) cs(y;x2¢¢¢) c(y) F¢¢ microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Average Total Cost Curves uFor any output level y, the long-run total cost curve always gives the lowest possible total production cost. uTherefore, the long-run av. total cost curve must always give the lowest possible av. total production cost. uThe long-run av. total cost curve must be the lower envelope of all of the firm’s short-run av. total cost curves. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Average Total Cost Curves u uE.g. suppose again that the firm can be in one of just three short-runs; x2 = x2¢ or x2 = x2¢¢ (x2¢ < x2¢¢ < x2¢¢¢) or x2 = x2¢¢¢ then the firm’s three short-run average total cost curves are ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Average Total Cost Curves uThe firm’s long-run average total cost curve is the lower envelope of the short-run average total cost curves ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) AC(y) The long-run av. total cost curve is the lower envelope of the short-run av. total cost curves. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uQ: Is the long-run marginal cost curve the lower envelope of the firm’s short-run marginal cost curves? microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uQ: Is the long-run marginal cost curve the lower envelope of the firm’s short-run marginal cost curves? uA: No. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uThe firm’s three short-run average total cost curves are ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢¢) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢¢) AC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢¢) AC(y) microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢¢) MC(y), the long-run marginal cost curve. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uFor any output level y > 0, the long-run marginal cost of production is the marginal cost of production for the short-run chosen by the firm. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› y $/output unit ACs(y;x2¢¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢¢) ACs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢) MCs(y;x2¢¢¢) MC(y), the long-run marginal cost curve. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uFor any output level y > 0, the long-run marginal cost is the marginal cost for the short-run chosen by the firm. uThis is always true, no matter how many and which short-run circumstances exist for the firm. microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves uFor any output level y > 0, the long-run marginal cost is the marginal cost for the short-run chosen by the firm. uSo for the continuous case, where x2 can be fixed at any value of zero or more, the relationship between the long-run marginal cost and all of the short-run marginal costs is ... microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves AC(y) $/output unit y SRACs microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves AC(y) $/output unit y SRMCs microlower.jpg © 2010 W. W. Norton & Company, Inc. ‹#› Short-Run & Long-Run Marginal Cost Curves AC(y) MC(y) $/output unit y SRMCs uFor each y > 0, the long-run MC equals the MC for the short-run chosen by the firm.