Public Economics Lecture 2: Market Efficiency Dr. Jonathan St¨abler Masaryk University Faculty of Economics and Administration Fall 2024 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 1 / 56 Outline of Lecture 2 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 2 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 3 / 56 Efficiency of Private Markets Private markets can lead to efficient resource allocation: ▶ Adam Smith’s ”invisible hand”: self-interest unintentionally promotes public interest. ▶ Entrepreneurs drive efficiency and innovation by responding to profit opportunities. ▶ If a good passes the ”market test” (value > production cost), it will be produced without government intervention. ▶ Competition eliminates inefficiencies and ensures better resource allocation. But: Market failures (e.g., unemployment, pollution) can prevent efficiency. ▶ The public sector can address these failures and enhance overall efficiency. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 4 / 56 Welfare Economics and Pareto Efficiency ▶ Welfare economics deals with normative questions: what to produce, how to produce, for whom, and who decides. ▶ How can we measure market efficiency and resource allocation? Pareto efficiency A resource allocation is Pareto efficient when it’s NOT possible to make someone better off without making someone else worse off − If we can find a way to make some people better off without making anybody else worse off, we have a Pareto improvement. − If an allocation allows for a Pareto improvement, it is called Pareto inefficient. − if an allocation is such that no Pareto improvements are possible, it is called Pareto efficient. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 5 / 56 Pareto Improvements and the Pareto Principle ▶ Pareto improvements occur when some are made better off without making anyone worse off. Example: A profitable bridge project is only a Pareto improvement if no one is negatively impacted. ▶ Not all changes meet this standard due to indirect effects (e.g., noise from infrastructure). ▶ Economists seek ”packages” of changes that together lead to Pareto improvements. Example: Reducing steel tariffs + raising taxes slightly to subsidize the steel industry. ▶ The Pareto principle suggests pursuing all Pareto improvements. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 6 / 56 Pareto Efficiency and Individualism ▶ Pareto efficiency is individualistic, focusing on each individual’s welfare rather than addressing inequality. ▶ A change that benefits the rich but leaves the poor unaffected can still be a Pareto improvement. ▶ Each individual’s perception of his or her own welfare that counts. −→ It respects consumer sovereignty: individuals are considered the best judges of their own needs and interests. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 7 / 56 Pareto-Efficiency Pareto efficiency implies the following: ▶ All resources are used efficiently in the production. ▶ All resources are allocated without waste. ▶ All trades, where both parties are (weakly) better off have already happened. Important Pareto efficiency does not imply an equal or fair distribution of resource allocations. Example: A change that makes the rich better off but leaves the poor unaffected is still a Pareto improvement. ▶ Pareto efficient allocations can be inequitable and socially undesirable. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 8 / 56 The Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics: 1. Theorem: If the economy is competitive, it is Pareto efficient. ▶ Competitive markets tend to automatically reach efficiency. There can be many efficient Pareto efficient allocations. 2. Theorem: Every Pareto efficient resource allocation can be obtained through a competitive market process with an initial redistribution of wealth. ▶ What if we want to obtain a particular distribution? If we transfer money from one individual to another, then let the market forces work, we will obtain another (different) Pareto efficient allocation. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 9 / 56 Decentralized vs. Centralized Systems ▶ Decentralized system: Decisions about production and consumption are made by firms and individuals. ▶ Centralized system: A single planner or agency makes all economic decisions (e.g., former Soviet Union, North Korea, Cuba). ▶ The second theorem shows that, with ideal conditions, decentralized competitive markets can be as efficient as centralized systems. ▶ The role of government should be limited to the redistribution of resources. A word of caution: theorems are logical propositions in which the conclusion follows from the assumptions. − Purely decentralized (private) systems do not work perfectly and there is need for public sector involvement. − Centralized system also don’t work (e.g., absence of price signal −→ difficulty to determine what is needed, concentration of power −→ dictatorship). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 10 / 56 What are your questions now? Let’s look more closely at the two welfare theorems. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 11 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 12 / 56 Competitive Equilibrium ▶ In deciding how much to demand and supply, individuals and firms equate the marginal benefit (MB) with the marginal cost (MC). ▶ The market will autonomously tend to reach the equilibrium point E, where demand equals supply. Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 13 / 56 Demand Curve: Consumer’s Problem ▶ Consumer receives utility U(x1) from consuming good x1 ▶ Each unit of good x1 costs p1 and hence creates costs C = x1p1 How much does she consume? argmax x1 U(x1) − x1p1 FOC : ∂(U(x1) − x1p1) ∂x1 = ∂U(x1) ∂x1 − p1 = 0 ⇐⇒ ∂U(x1) ∂x1 marginal benefit of consumption = p1 marginal costs of consumption SOC : ∂2(U(x1) − x1p1) ∂x2 1 < 0 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 14 / 56 Demand Curve: Consumer’s Problem However, consumers not only consume one good, but face trade-offs between spending their income on the product/ service of interest x1 and all other products and services, represented by x2. Additionally, they have an upper limit of how much they can spend m. ▶ Consumer receives utility U(x1, x2) from consuming goods x1 and x2 ▶ She faces the budget constraint p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m ▶ where pi is the price of good i and m the income argmax x1,x2 U(x1, x2) s.t.p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 15 / 56 Demand Curve: Consumer’s Problem Source: Varian () Figure 2.3 ▶ Budget constraint: the amount of income a consumer can spend on various goods. ▶ Change in one of the prices (here p1), changes the slope of the budget line: −p1 p2 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 16 / 56 Demand Curve: Consumer’s Problem Source: Varian (2010) Figure 3.11 ▶ Indifference curve: Gives the combination of x1 and x2, which give the same level of utility. ▶ Marginal rate of substitution (∆x2 ∆x1 ): The amount of x1 that an individual is willing to give up in exchange for a unit of x2. ▶ Optimal Choice: Where the slope of the budget line equals the MRS : −∆x2 ∆x1 = −p1 p2 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 17 / 56 Consumer’s Problem – The Lagrangian Method argmax x1,x2 U(x1, x2); s.t.p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m Set up the Lagrangian function and maximize it: L = U(x1, x2) − λ(m − p1x1 − p2x2) ∂L ∂x1 = ∂U ∂x1 + λp1 = 0 −→ ∂U ∂x1 1 p1 = −λ (1) ∂L ∂x2 = ∂U ∂x2 + λp2 = 0 −→ ∂U ∂x2 1 p2 = −λ (2) ∂L ∂λ = m − p1x1 − p2x2 = 0 −→ m = p1x1 + p2x2 (3) Combining (1) and (2) leads to: − ∂U/∂x1 ∂U/∂x2 Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) = − p1 p2 Slope of Budget Line Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 18 / 56 Demand Curve: Individual Demand Source: Varian (2010) Figure 6.9 ▶ Indifference curve: Gives the combination of x1 and x2, which give the same level of utility. ▶ If p1 decreases, demand for x1 increases. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 19 / 56 Demand Curve: Individual Demand Source: Mankiw (2018) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 20 / 56 Demand Curve: Market Demand Source: Mankiw (2018) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 21 / 56 Supply Curve: Firm’s Problem Suppose a firm faces perfect competition: ▶ Large number of consumers and producers ▶ Free market entry and exit ▶ No transaction costs ▶ Complete information =⇒ Each firm’s output (qi ) is marginal and does not affect the market price P(Q). Q = n i=1 qi and lim n→∞ qi Q = 0 =⇒ The firm takes the market price as given (exogenous market price). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 22 / 56 Supply Curve: Firm’s Problem The firm takes the market price P as given (exogenous price) and maximizes its profit π by choosing the quantity q to produce, given the cost function C(q). π profit = Pq revenue − C(q) variable costs − F fixed costs FOC : ∂π ∂q = P − ∂C(q) ∂q = 0 ⇐⇒ P marginal revenue = ∂C(q) ∂q marginal costs (MC) SOC : ∂2π ∂q2 < 0 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 23 / 56 Supply Curve: Firm’s Problem Source: Varian (2010) Figure 22.2 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 24 / 56 Supply Curve: Individual Supply Source: Mankiw (2018) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 25 / 56 Supply Curve: Market Supply Source: Mankiw (2018) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 26 / 56 Competitive Equilibrium ▶ In deciding how much to demand and supply, individuals and firms equate the marginal benefit (MB) with the marginal cost (MC). ▶ The market will autonomously tend to reach the equilibrium point E, where demand equals supply. [video] Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 27 / 56 Are there any questions? From focusing on a single market, let’s zoom out and look at the welfare of the population overall and the production possibilities overall. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 28 / 56 From Competitive Equilibrium to Economic Efficiency ▶ So far, we explored the concept of competitive equilibrium in a single market. ▶ Key Point: In a competitive equilibrium, prices adjust so that supply equals demand, ensuring no excess supply or demand in that market. ▶ Link to efficiency of an entire economy: ▶ Competitive equilibrium is a necessary condition for economic efficiency. ▶ Now, we extend this idea to evaluate efficiency across the whole economy. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 29 / 56 Analyzing Economic Efficiency Three Aspects of Pareto Efficiency: 1. Exchange Efficiency: ▶ Goods must be allocated to those who value them most. ▶ Example: chocolate ice cream to a person who prefers chocolate, vanilla to someone who prefers vanilla. 2. Production Efficiency: ▶ Output maximized with the available resources. ▶ Production efficiency occurs when an economy cannot produce more of one good without sacrificing another (given fixed resources). 3. Product Mix Efficiency: ▶ Goods produced should match individual preferences. ▶ Example: if people prefer ice cream over apples and it’s cheaper to produce, more ice cream should be produced. Together, these conditions lead to Pareto Efficiency of the entire economy. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 30 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 31 / 56 Exchange Efficiency: Utility Possibility Curve Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ The utility possibilities curve represents the maximum utility that can be achieved by two consumers. ▶ A Pareto efficient economy operates along this curve, where improving one person’s utility would reduce another’s. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 32 / 56 Exchange Efficiency: Utility Possibility Curve Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ 1st theorem: When markets are competitive, the economy lies on the utility possibilities curve and is Pareto efficient. ▶ 2nd theorem: Any point on the curve can be reached by redistributing initial wealth. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 33 / 56 Budget Constraints: Crusoe’s Example Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ Crusoe has $100 to spend on apples and oranges. Apples cost $1 each, and oranges cost $2 each. ▶ Crusoe’s budget constraint shows the trade-off: for every orange he buys, he must give up two apples. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 34 / 56 Indifference Curves: Crusoe’s Preferences Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Figure 3.4 ▶ Indifference curves represent combinations of goods yielding the same utility; e.g., curve I0 indicates combinations equally attractive to 80 apples and 18 oranges (point A). Points A, B, C,D, E are all equally attractive. ▶ The slope of the indifference curve reflects the marginal rate of substitution (MRS), showing how many apples Crusoe is willing to give up for an additional orange. ▶ As Crusoe consumes more oranges, the MRS diminishes; he requires less apples to compensate for giving up oranges. ▶ The optimal choice occurs where the highest indifference curve is tangent to the budget constraint −→ −MRS = −p1 p2 (point E). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 35 / 56 Exchange Efficiency ▶ Exchange efficiency occurs when goods are distributed so that no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off. ▶ It ensures that there is no room for further trades that would benefit both parties. ▶ Example: − Crusoe is willing to trade 1 orange for 1 apple. − Friday, on the other hand, is willing to trade 3 apples for 1 orange. − They agree to a trade: Crusoe gives Friday 1 orange, and Friday gives Crusoe 2 apples. − After the trade, both are better off: Crusoe gets 2 apples (but only wanted 1), and Friday only gives up 2 apples (but was willing to give 3). ▶ After this trade, Crusoe and Friday move to new points on their indifference curves, each with a new marginal rate of substitution (MRS). − Crusoe likely desires more apples to compensate for giving up oranges (as he has fewer oranges and more apples now). − Friday would be willing to give up fewer apples for a new orange (as he has more oranges and less apples now). − Trade is efficient (and will occur) until both have the same marginal rate of substitution. ▶ Exchange efficiency requires that after trade, Crusoe and Friday have the same marginal rate of substitution (MRS). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 36 / 56 Exchange Efficiency Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ The Edgeworth–Bowley box shows all allocations of goods between Crusoe (bottom left) and Friday (top right). ▶ Pareto efficiency is achieved at point E, where Friday’s highest indifference curve is tangent to Crusoe’s, equalizing their marginal rates of substitution. [[click for video]] Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 37 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 38 / 56 Production Efficiency: Production Possibilities Frontier Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ The Production possibility frontier shows all possibly combinations of production levels of apples and oranges. ▶ The production possibilities frontier illustrates the trade-off between producing apples and oranges. ▶ Production efficiency occurs when an economy cannot produce more of one good without sacrificing another (given fixed resources). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 39 / 56 Production Efficiency Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Figure 3.7 ▶ Assume that all we need for producing anything is land and labor. ▶ The isocost line represents combinations of inputs (e.g., land and labor) that yield the same total cost. ▶ Isoquants show combinations of inputs that produce the same output level, similar to how indifference curves illustrate consumer preferences. ▶ The marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) reflects the amount of one input that must be increased to compensate for a decrease in another input. ▶ The optimal input choice occurs where the highest isoquant is tangent to the isocost line: −→ − MRTS = −p1 p2 Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 40 / 56 Production Efficiency ▶ Production efficiency occurs when firms allocate resources such that no firm can increase output without reducing output for another firm. ▶ It ensures that there is no room for further reallocations of inputs that would benefit both firms. ▶ Example: − Firm A is willing to trade 1 unit of labor for 2 units of land. − Firm B, on the other hand, is willing to trade 3 units of land for 1 unit of labor. − They agree to a trade: Firm A gives Firm B 1 unit of labor, and Firm B gives Firm A 2 units of land. − After the trade, both firms are better off: Firm A acquires 2 units of land (but only wanted 1), while Firm B gives up only 2 units of land (but was willing to give up 3). ▶ After this trade, both firms move to new points on their isoquants, each with a new marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). − Firm A likely desires more land to compensate for having given up some labor. − Firm B would be willing to give up fewer units of land for additional labor, as it now has more labor and fewer land units. − An exchange in production inputs is efficient (and will continue) until both firms have the same marginal rate of technical substitution. ▶ Production efficiency requires that after the trade, Firm A and Firm B have the same marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 41 / 56 Production Efficiency Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) ▶ The Edgeworth–Bowley box illustrates all allocations of inputs (land and labor) between Firm O (bottom left) and Firm O’ (top right). ▶ Pareto efficiency is achieved at point E, where Firm O’s highest isoquant is tangent to Firm O”s, equalizing their marginal rates of technical substitution (MRTS). Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 42 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 43 / 56 Product Mix Efficiency ▶ Product mix efficiency considers both technical feasibility and individuals’ preferences when it comes to choosing the best mix of apples and oranges. ▶ The slope of the production possibilities curve is called the marginal rate of transformation (MRT). ▶ Under perfect competition, MRT = MRS. Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 44 / 56 Basic Conditions for Pareto Efficiency 1. Exchange Efficiency: The marginal rate of substitution between any two goods must be the same for all individuals. 2. Production Efficiency: The marginal rate of technical substitution between any two inputs must be the same for all firms. 3. Product Mix Efficiency: The marginal rate of transformation must equal the marginal rate of substitution. 1. Theorem: If the economy is competitive, it is Pareto efficient... ...because it satisfies all three conditions. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 45 / 56 Outline 1. Pareto-Efficiency and Welfare Economics 2. Welfare Theorem 1 2.1 Competitive Equilibrium 2.2 Exchange Efficiency 2.3 Production Efficiency 2.4 Product Mix Efficiency 3. Welfare Theorem 2 3.1 Definition 3.2 Equity and Efficiency Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 46 / 56 Welfare Theorem 2 1. Theorem: If the economy is competitive, it is Pareto efficient. 2. Theorem: Every Pareto efficient resource allocation can be obtained through a competitive market process with an initial redistribution of wealth. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 47 / 56 Welfare Theorem 2 ▶ Even with no market failures, free market outcomes might generate substantial inequality. ▶ Inequality is often viewed as the biggest issue with market economies. 2nd Welfare Theorem: ▶ Any Pareto Efficient allocation can be achieved by: 1. Suitable redistribution of initial endowments (e.g., individualized lump-sum taxes based on individual characteristics, not behavior) 2. Then, letting markets work freely. =⇒ No conflict between efficiency and equity. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 48 / 56 Example: 2nd Welfare Theorem ▶ Suppose the economy is populated by 50% disabled people who are unable to work (earning $0) and 50% able people who can work and earn $100. ▶ Free market outcome: Disabled individuals have $0, able individuals have $100. 2nd Welfare Theorem: ▶ The government can identify the disabled and the able (even if the able do not work). ▶ Redistribution: The government can tax the able by $50 (regardless of whether they work) and give $50 to each disabled person. ▶ The able will continue working because if they don’t, they would still have to pay $50 and earn zero income. ▶ Both able and disabled individuals have $50 in the end. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 49 / 56 Example: Welfare Theorem 2 ▶ Suppose that households supply labour (L) and consume a single good (X) ▶ Two types of households 1 and 2: ▶ Different productivity levels (wage): w1 and w2, with w1 < w2 ▶ Same utility from consumption and free time (1-L): logU1 = logU2 = αlogX + (1 − α)log(1 − L) where α ∈ (0, 1) ▶ Household 1 consumes X1 units of the product, and household 2 X2. Together, they cannot consume more than they produce and thus face the production constraint: X1 + X2 = w1L1 + w2L2 argmax L1,L2,X1,X2 logU1 + logU2 s.t.X1 + X2 = w1L1 + w2L2 Source: Atkinson and Stiglitz (2015) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 50 / 56 Example: Solving Solving this problem (see Atkinson and Stiglitz (2015), p.285ff), the utility levels for household 1 and 2 are: ▶ U1 = Awα 1 ▶ U2 = Awα 2 The more productive household (w2 > w1) receives more utility, because they work more efficiently and hence can either buy more products and/ or enjoy more free-time. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 51 / 56 Example: Welfare Theorem 2 ▶ The more productive household 2 (w2 > w1) receives more utility than household 1 (point N). ▶ How can we reach other Pareto efficient allocations on this possibility frontier, (e.g. point E)? =⇒ 2nd Welfare Theorem: ’simply’ transfer some initial wealth from household 2 to household 1. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 52 / 56 Example: Welfare Theorem 2 2nd Welfare Theorem: every Pareto efficient resource allocation can be obtained through a competitive market process with an initial redistribution of wealth. ▶ Let there be a lump-sum transfer T, where household 2 transfers some wealth T to household 1. ▶ Then the individual budget constraints are: X1 = w1L1 + T and X2 = w2L2 − T −→ Household 2 has to work more to reach the same consumption level −→ Household 1 has to work less to reach the same consumption level Solving this new problem (see Atkinson and Stiglitz (2015), p.285ff) yields the new individual utility levels: ▶ U1 = A(w1 + T)w −(1−α) 1 ▶ U2 = A(w2 − T)w −(1−α) 2 Plugging in any T will move us on the utility possibility frontier. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 53 / 56 Why would we want to redistribute wealth? ▶ Equality means each individual or group of people is given the same resources or opportunities. ▶ Equity recognizes that each person has different circumstances and allocates the exact resources and opportunities needed to reach an equal outcome. Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 54 / 56 Readings for Next Week 3 Market Failure Main Reading: Stiglitz and Rosengard (2015) Chapter 4: Market Failure Recommended Reading: Varian (2010) Chapter 37: Asymmetric Information (37.1, 37.2, 37.3, 37.4, and 37.5) Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 55 / 56 Thank you and see you next week! Jonathan.Stabler@econ.muni.cz Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 56 / 56 References I Atkinson, A. B. and Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). Lectures on public economics: Updated edition, Princeton University Press. Mankiw, N. G. (2018). Intermediate macroeconomics (8th edition). Stiglitz, J. E. and Rosengard, J. K. (2015). Economics of the public sector (4th edition). Varian, H. (2010). Intermediate microeconomics. a modern approach (8th edition)., NY: University of California at Berkeley . Public Economics 2 Market Efficiency Fall 2024 56 / 56