/ The Development of Welfare States in Europe and America Edited by PETER FLORA and ARNOLD J. HEIDENHEIMER O Transaction Publishers New Brunswick (U.S.A.) and London (U.K.) 22 THE DEVELOPMENT OF WELFARE STATES Europe. These considerations make it more understandable that the welfare state should have become more vulnerable to attack in Britain than in most other countries. For those who seek to predict the future, as for those who want to understand better the past, this volume seeks to distill some answers from the century that has elapsed since the German emperor delivered his social message in 1881. But to encompass the broad analyses required by such a task makes it necessary to incorporate the experiences of individual nations—be it Germany the innovator, or Britain the adapter and propagator—into the larger body of experience. II. The Welfare State as an Answer to Developmental Problems We can try to define the core of the welfare state and to delineate its changing boundaries by seeing it as a more or less conscious or reactive response to long-term processes and basic development problems. But what were these developments and problems? To this fundamental question of classical macrosociology we of course find different answers in the works of de Tocqueville or Weber, Marx or Durkheim. But they would agree that, in the context of European history, the growth of the modern welfare state can be understood as a response to two fundamental developments: the formation of national states and their transformation into mass democracies after the French Revolution, and the growth of capitalism that became the dominant mode of production after the Industrial Revolution. The prehistory of the modern welfare state, the "Poor Law Period,"16 was closely related to the early state building efforts of fifteenth- and sixteenth-century Europe. The later consolidation of the absolutist state was accompanied by a gradual, though by no means continuous, "nationalization," differentiation, and extension of welfare institutions. National differences within Europe in the creation of absolutist states with strong bureaucracies and paternalistic traditions may explain the earlier or later beginnings of the welfare states (for example, Germany versus Great Britain or Sweden versus Switzerland). The real beginning of the modern welfare state, however, had to await the transformation of the absolutist state into mass democracy in the last third of the nineteenth century, after a variable intermediary period of liberal democracy with restricted suffrage. In thus linking welfare state development with the evolution of mass democracy, one may interpret the welfare state as an answer to increasing demands for socioeconomic equality or as the institutionalization of social rights relative to the development of civil and political rights.17 But the welfare state is far more than the mere product of mass democ- Historical Core and Changing Boundaries of the Welfare State 23 racy. It implies a basic transformation of the state itself, of its structure, functions, and legitimacy. In a Weberian tradition, the growth of the welfare state may be understood as the gradual emergence of a new system of domination consisting of "distributing elites," "service bureaucracies," and "social clienteles."18 With the structural transformation of the state, the basis of its legitimacy and its functions also change. The objectives of external strength or security, internal economic freedom, and equality before the law are increasingly replaced by a new raison d'etre: the provision of secure social services and transfer payments in a standard and routinized way that is not restricted to emergency assistance. At this point, however, the welfare state is no longer primarily interpreted as a response to the demand for socioeconomic equality, but to the demand for socioeconomic security. We turn from the evolution of mass democracy and the transformation of the nation state to the second fundamental development in modern European history: the growth of capitalism. In the Marxist tradition, the welfare state is seen as an attempt to deal with specific problems of capitalist development, class conflict and recurring economic crises: welfare measures represent an effort to integrate the working classes without fundamental challenge to the institution and distribution of private property. As with the early state building efforts, the prehistory of the welfare state is also tied to the emergence of capitalism in sixteenth-century Europe—to a growing labor market, agrarian capitalism, rural unemployment, and overpopulation. And as with the democratic transformation of the state, the creation of the modern welfare state did not precede the aggravation of business cycle effects and the intensification of organized class conflict in the last decades of the nineteenth century. Both perspectives—that of political sociology in the tradition of de Tocqueville and Weber, and that of political economy in the tradition of Marx and others—do not necessarily contradict one another and may in fact be complementary. They are an expression of the historical constellation in which the European welfare state emerged, a constellation of growing mass democracies and expanding capitalist economies within a system of sovereign national states. In Chapter 2, it will be shown, however, that the most democratic and capitalist of the European societies at that time were not the first to develop the institutions and policies of the modern welfare state. Furthermore, the fascist states after World War I did not completely change these institutions and even developed them to some extent. Finally, the experience of Russia after 191719 illustrates that nondemocratic and noncapitalist societies have established very similar institutions. Thus, the welfare state seems to be a far more general phenomenon of modernization, not exclusively tied to its "democratic-capitalist" version. The generality of this phenomenon may be illuminated by some of 24 THE DEVELOPMENT OF WELFARE STATES Durkheim's ideas and concepts. Using his perspective, the welfare state may be understood as an attempt to create a new kind of solidarity in highly differentiated societies and as an attempt to respond to problems in the division of labor, which for him is the basic process of structural change in modernizing societies. Division of labor weakens old associations and intermediary powers and thus increases the opportunities for individualization. Responding to the need to regulate the manifold new exchange processes, social life is centralized. These fundamental processes are reflected in the institutions of the welfare state; public bureaucracies take over many of the functions formerly filled by smaller social units, and their services and transfer payments tend to become more and more individualized. In Durkheim's view, the integration of highly differentiated societies is threatened by two main problems: anomie and inequality. His famous concept of anomie refers to a lack of normative or moral regulation that manifests itself on two levels: social relationships and individual personalities.20 He first applied this concept to the unregulated socioeconomic relationships produced by the growth of the capitalist market economy that resulted in recurring economic instability and increasing industrial conflict. He later extended it to define an imbalance between individual needs and wants and the means of satisfying them. From a Durkheimian point of view, the contemporary welfare state represents' only a partial, and to some extent inadequate, answer to the problems of anomie. The democratic welfare states have met with only limited success in attempting to institutionalize industrial relations and conflicts and to stabilize markets. Although they have developed institutions of income maintenance and tried to secure the provision of specific services, they still respond primarily to material needs and have remained somewhat helpless in shaping and defining those needs themselves. Thus the welfare state would here represent an answer not to the more general problem of anomie in modern societies, but rather to the limited problem of economic insecurity. This limitation may explain some of the more recent problems of the welfare states in creating feelings of security and satisfaction.21 The fact that economic security is usually called social security is perhaps a hint of this underlying difficulty. For Durkheim, the answer to the problem of anomie was normative regulation. In order to create solidarity, however, such regulation had to be considered just, which for him meant equality of opportunity and just contract on the basis of an equality of exchange conditions. In the Western cultural tradition as a whole, however, the concept of equality is broader and has two different meanings that are at least partially contradictory.22 The first is a major component of the socialist ethic, often called equality of result. It implies an equalization in the disposal of resources, commodities, msioncai L.ore ana <^nanging Boundaries 01 the Wellare State 25 and services, a redistribution according to needs. In interpreting the welfare state as a response to equality demands of this kind, one must distinguish between efforts to establish national minima (poor relief, minimum wage, national pensions, compulsory education, certain social services) and efforts at redistribution in a stricter sense (above all, progressive income taxation). This distinction has been of great historical importance and still has institutional consequences. The second meaning, a major component of liberal ethic, is equality of opportunity and is most relevant in the field of public education. The development of comprehensive secondary education would be an example of an attempt to realize this principle. In its emphasis on merit, however, equality of opportunity inherently legitimizes inequality, mainly in the form of income and status differences. This is most obvious in income-related social insurance programs and the higher levels of public education financed by general taxes. Security and equality are here seen as the two fundamental dimensions of the welfare state. These dimensions may be shown graphically, in Figure 1.1. This schematic view, however, does not answer empirical questions about the relative importance of these two objectives or the degree to which they have been realized. Has the goal of security always been more important than the goal of equality? What were the different priorities among the Western nations and how have they changed overtime? Furthermore, both objectives may interact to supplement as well as contradict one another. Thus, as soon as social security develops into a security of social status, it contributes to the stabilization of inequality. But in so doing, even such a stabilization modifies inequality in that the poorer parts of the population have usually been the most insecure. There are three basic means by which the welfare state pursues its goals: the direct payment of cash benefits, the direct provision of services in kind, and the indirect extension of benefits through tax deductions and credits. The essential function of transfer payments, the first of these means, is income maintenance for typical phases of nonemployment in the life cycle (maternity, childhood/parenthood, education and training, old-age, widowhood), typical situations of employment incapacity (sickness, injuries, invalidity), and unemployment among the active labor force. These benefits may be financed either with earmarked taxes or general revenues. In addition, benefits in cash and kind such as public assistance may be given in less standardized situations of need that are not covered by differentiated income maintenance schemes. An analysis of transfer payments must also take into account family allowances and subsidies for specific goods and services ("vouchers"). The direct public provision of services in kind is the second basic instrument of the welfare state. In interpreting and evaluating this means, one has to see it in close connection with governmental intervention in 26 THE DEVELOPMENT OF WELFARE STATES Figure 1.1 Dimensions of the Welfare State Redistribution >* Eh M national ^ minima a "Social" w SECURITY/INSECURITY security E-« H