1 94 Energy during the interwar years Colombian Petroleum. 1920-1940," Canadian Journal of History, 9 (August 1974), pp. 179-96; Rippy. "US and Colombian Oil," pp. 19-35; Chester, US Oil Policy, pp. 144-7; Wilkins. Multinational Enterprise, pp. 255-72. 56. J. Foreman-Peck, .-1 History of the World Economy: lnernational Economic Relations since 1850. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books (1983), p. 213; for a concise analysis of the worst years of the depression, see P. Fearon, The Origins and Nature of the Great Slump, 1929-1932, Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press (1979). 57. For the above three paragraphs: S. Takahashi, Japan and World Resources, Tokyo: Kenkyusha Press (1937) and Royal Institute of International Affairs. Information Department, Raw Materials and Colonies. New York: Oxford University Press (1936) summarize the conflicting positions of the Axis powers and their antagonists. See also, Schumpeter, Industrialization of Japan, pp. 43-4, 373-5, passim; Takahashi, Japan, p. 29; C.C. Concannon et al., World Chemical Developments in 1935. US Department of Commerce. Bureau of Foreign and Domestic Commerce. Trade Information Bulletin No. 832, Washington, DC: GPO (1936), pp. 19, 23, 29, 36; tvl. Erselcuk, "Japan's Oil Resources," Economic Geography, 22 (January 1946), p. 16; Anderson, Standard-Vacuum, pp. 80-7; Chester, US Oil Policy, pp. 297-301; World Petroleum, 13 (January 1942), pp. 23-7. 4_ Energy flows in a politically polarized world World War II strongly influenced the energy future of the world. To the victor come the spoils. Had the war commencing in 1939 been concluded on terms favorable to the Axis powers, one might imagine them in possession of the Soviet Union's Baku fields, much of the Middle East, and the Netherlands East Indies. What an impact such an outcome would have had on the Allied powers and on the giant firms that dominated the world oil industry. Far more was at risk than oil or other natural resources, but one can still conjecture that the economies and societies of Britain, the USA, and other nations would have evolved quite differently had the Axis dictated terms of access to Middle East oil. Energy and World War II Each of the major belligerents committed substantial resources to securing a fuel supply sufficient for the prosecution of a highly mobilized conflict fought on distant and shifting fronts. Germany and Japan, without domestic oil reserves and the latter without adequate coal, planned campaigns to conquer fuel-producing regions while investing heavily during the 1930s in the development of synthetic fuel technologies. In both nations the production of coal, the chief feed stock for synthetics, cnjo\cd high pnonK. Neither Britain nor the United States made provisions belore 1939 for an emergency fuel supply. The UK felt reasonably secure. British companies controlled the largest oil fields in the Middle East and operated successHilK in sate regions in the western hemisphere. A more than adequate domestic coal supply was available. For its part, the USA 95 96 Energy in a politically polarized world Energy and World War II 97 possessed large and accessible petroleum and coal reserves and dominated the oil industries of South America and Saudi Arabia, the latter's potential still unrecognized. The USSR, with enormous productive potential in all fuels, experienced the destruction or seizure of much of its western based coal industry and its Baku oil fields. With great effort and the provision of several lend lease refineries by the USA, the Soviet Union produced and refined about 60 percent of its petroleum needs.1 The belligerents grossly miscalculated their energy requirements. Germany and Japan possessed stocks and access to supplies sufficient only for a relatively short war. Germany's conquests in Europe added the sizable coal production of Poland and France, some part necessarily devoted to sustaining the conquered populations, the oil fields of Romania, and the Maikop fields of the northern Caucasus, the latter so thoroughly destroyed by retreating Soviets that they added nothing to the oil stock of the Third Reich. Neither did the other conquests yield more than marginal increments to fuel supplies. By 1943, heavy and sustained Allied air attacks pulverized Germany's fuel industry, particularly the synthetics complex, and its transportation links. Oil became desperately short by 1944. Shortages of aviation gasoline severely hampered the operation of the Luftwaffe during the last year of the war. As labor productivity declined, partially due to malnutrition among miners, coal production in occupied France and Belgium fell off severely by 1943. Maintenance and transportation services also became increasingly inadequate. Forced labor in German mines maintained the labor force at adequate levels, but dreadful working conditions resulted in low productivity. Falling supplies of coal in 1943 and 1944 hamstrung the production of iron and steel and synthetic fuels. Japan launched its war against the USA and other European states with a natural resource base more limited than that of Germany. The need for oil determined that Japan would strike south to seize the Netherlands East Indies. Japan's hopes rested on the fatally optimistic assumption that the USA would not persist in a long and costly struggle. With a much less developed synthetic fuel industry than Germany, Japan depended upon ocean transport for the bulk of its oil and some of its coal. American control of the sea lanes by late 1944 placed virtually each Japanese oil tanker at risk. By early 1945, Japan's oil stocks had dwindled lo under one million barrels. An almost total blockade of the home islands by US naval and air forces denied Japan access to the oii of Southeast Asia. Shortages of oil and coal severely constrained war industries. Perhaps even more deadly in 1945 was the looming specter of widespread starvation.: British complacency in 1939 about fuel supplies gave way to despair by 1940. As German piano pounded the UK. submarines sunk an increasing tonnage of tankers. The intercession of the USA in 1940 through the exchange of American destroyers for bases in British possessions, the Lend Lease Act of March 1941, and the transfer of fifty oil tankers to Britain in May 1941 relieved the situation. Petroleum stocks climbed well above the danger zone. Although Nazi submarines destroyed an enormous tonnage of tankers after America's entry into the war, supplies from America were not jeopardized. The destruction of Axis armies in North Africa in 1942 eliminated the threat to the Suez and the Persian Gulf oil fields. Thereafter, American production supplemented by Venezuelan and Middle Eastern oil provided more than adequate fuel to Allied forces. Military demands for fuel compelled the heavy intervention of the British and American governments in their energy industries. In the USA, a complex of federal agencies successfully maintained adequate production of fuels, particularly aviation gasoline and chemical feedstocks for synthetic rubber, distributed fuels to the Allies and to domestic wartime industries without totally denying supplies to non-critical industries or the civilian sector, and moderated inflationary pressures. But these agencies and the policies they implemented were swiftly abandoned in 1945 and 1946. America preferred, as in 1918, to return to an essentially unregulated regimen for petroleum and coal.3 A prewar heritage in the UK of intermittent government intervention in the coal industry and in the energy utilities combined with severe wartime conditions to propel Britain toward national ownership. Beginning in 1939 all energy was strictly rationed, far more so than in the USA. By 1943, the Ministry of Fuel and Power controlled coal prices and miners' wages, an intervention necessitated by inflationary pressures, labor scarcity, and other operational problems. The government operated the mines while the mine owners retained financial responsibility. The Labour Party called for the immediate nationalization of coal. While the Conservative Party resisted this demand, it supported continuing state authority to compel industry rationalization. Labour's electoral victory after the war led immediately to the nationalization of coal and the electric and gas utilities.4 While petroleum remained in private hands in both Britain and the USA. the foreign policies of both nations presumed continued access to cheap oil. thus assuring a competitive/cooperative Anglo-American relationship concerning foreign fields. Britain's dependency upon foreign oil was total but the national energy mix during and immediately after the war still reflected the dominance of coal which, in 1950. provided 90 percent of total primar\ energs requirements.^ America's consumption of oil was far greater, with all but a fraction supplied domesticalh. In both nation1-, knowledgeable ::0 •.the Othe; j'nn'mi'j, '.ne.ig\ s.OUi'Ces. EiKmiS U, ^guiine. natural gas succumbed to Truman and Eisenhower vetoes. That the artificially low natural gas prices fixed by the Federal Power Commission and b\ dozens of state and municipal regulatory bodies robbed the coal industry of markets, encouraged wasteful use of a premium fuei. and acted as a disincentive to the development of ne*' iv-c-r seemed 114 Energy in a politically polarized world Trends in energy use to 1960 115 a matter of supreme indifference to everyone save the gas industry. Electricity remained highly regulated. Prices were kept low, partially by using cheap natural gas and fuel oil as boiler fuels. Electricity use shot upward; US per capita consumption rose from 1,136 kwh in 1937 to 5,947 kwh in 1965, 2.6 times greater than average EEC consumption. Analysts of US energy policies have lavished especial attention on the emergence of the USA as a net oil importer after 1948 and on the imposition of voluntary oil import quotas in 1955 and mandatory quotas in 1959. Suffice it to remark here that quotas were adopted at the behest of the domestic oil industry and aimed at raising domestic production, stimulating exploration, and shoring up domestic prices, all of which, it was argued, were necessary to national security. A rare breed these quotas, perhaps the only fully implemented federal energy policy before the 1960s. This, rather than their intrinsic importance, may partly explain their magnet-like attraction for analysts. Perhaps more important in the long run, defense considerations stymied research on the peaceful application of nuclear energy until President Eisenhower's Atoms for Peace address at the UN in 1953 partially raised the lid of secrecy. This new tack encouraged the private sector and the Atomic Energy Commission to cooperate in research and development. While private sector markets for nuclear reactors failed immediately to materialize in the USA or in Europe, the new policy did promote bilateral agreements and led to subsequent payouts. Prior to the speech, the tightly veiled nature of atomic research fostered the pursuit of dead ends and less efficient reactor technologies. By the mid-1950s, the USA, France, Britain, and the USSR were committed to their own schemes, as Canada and Sweden would be soon after. Once the USA adopted a policy of promoting nuclear power it pursued this goal without regard to its impact on coal, with inadequate attention to reactor safety and siting, and with callous indifference to the inevitable need to dispose of irradiated waste and obsolete equipment. Great publicity and ballyhoo attended the "freeing" of nuclear energy for peaceful uses. The American public, however, received little information about costs, about federal subsidies, about the concentration of research funds and knowledge in very few firms, about who should own and pay for nuclear plants, or about safety and environmental impacts. Scientists and government officials in the USA and elsewhere apparently believed the general public incapable of understanding such complex technical issues. The forces governing the energy mix of the USA were well recognized prior to the war. Coal's share declined after World War 1 as oil and natural gas use spread. This process was essentially complete by 1955 (Table 4.5). Overall, the US energy mix reflected the domestic availability of fossil fuels and consumer preferences for gas or oil rather than coal, choices abetted by gas prices that were fixed too low and by access to cheap oil. The absence of focused energy policies in the USA encouraged results similar to the more comprehensive policies of European nations, that is a growing dependence upon oil imported from potentially insecure countries and a coal industry in disarray.27 The energy mix of the lesser developed countries (LDCs) Dozens of former colonial peoples trod the exhilarating but painful path to independence after World War II. Other peoples, possessed of sovereignty for generations, as in Latin America, labored under economic, social, and political disadvantages hardly less burdensome than those shouldered by the recently liberated. In some countries, Indonesia and Algeria for example, independence only came as a result of bloody revolutions. In few places did independence pour forth the sweet fruits of economic prosperity and political stability. Decades, if not centuries, of exploitative colonial rule had not prepared the newly free nations for the competitive conditions of the modern world. Internal divisions, based on class, race, and tribe, precluded the evolution of political stability and spawned recurring coups and counter-coups. Overwhelmingly rural and agricultural, engaged in primitive, subsistence farming, enmeshed in a colonial economy even after independence, with high fertility rates and declining death rates unaccompanied by the creation of sufficient employment, these peoples remained mired in abject poverty. The energy mix of the LDCs reflected their economic backwardness. Indonesia, with significant oil reserves, depended in 1970 upon noncommercial (organic) energy sources for 75 percent of its total energy requirements, a proportion that remained over 50 percent in 1982. Brazil, energy dependent, consistently used non-commercial fuels for over 30 percent of TPER from 1970 through 1982, a share that exceeded 50 percent until the mid-1960s. In 1970, India relied on traditional organic fuels —wood, cow dung —for 90 percent of its energy and managed to reduce that figure to 70 percent by 1983. Raising the per capita consumption of commercial energy necessitated the introduction of new technologies, both large and small. More easily accomplished in urban areas than rural, LDC governments naturally focused their efforts on the cities, foolishly permitting rural 116 Energy in a politically polarized world The post World War II oil boom 117 areas to stagnate. Nothing seemed to work. Shortages of funds, ignorance of technologies, autocratic governments, landed elites, a smothering illiteracy, and on and on, obstructed steady progress. Within each LDC a few benefited from modernization, but most did not. Rural villagers unable to make a living on their small plots fled to the permanent unemployment and cultural despair of life in Lagos. Sáo Paulo, or Manila.28 The wealthy nations of the West provided insufficient development aid via bilateral arrangements or through such institutions as the Internationa! Bank for Reconstruction and Development (World Bank) and the International Monetary Fund. The World Bank preferred to support giant projects when less complex and smaller-scale technologies might have been more suitable. Into the 1970s, the World Bank refused to lend money to national oil companies, always advocating development through private enterprise. Neither India nor Brazil, seeking a modicum of oil independence through state ownership of production and refining, were able to secure financing from the West. Electrification efforts in the LDCs received support if the utility was privately owned, which usually meant that it was a subsidiary of a British or American holding company. For the most part, the energy importing LDCs remained captive markets for the MNOCs. India, countries in West Africa, and other LDCs entered into importing and refining agreements with the MNOCs when weak and ignorant of the oil industry. Competition was eliminated and prices kept high. India's effort to break this stranglehold by building national refineries and importing Soviet oil at cheaper prices encountered stiff MNOC resistance. The question for India (and other LDCs), as Dasgupta suggests, was the binding nature of agreements concluded when India possessed neither knowledge nor leverage and which fastened disadvantageous terms on the nation. During the 1950s, a mixed response to that question emanated from the LDCs. Iran answered with a resounding "no" and nationalized the oil industry in 1950. This step was not emulated by other Middle Eastern nations. Host government resentment smoldered for a time. Latin American states waffled, motivated on the one hand by nationalistic pressure for state control over resouices and key economic sectors, and, on the other hand, by a persistent and increasing need for foreign capital. India forced the American & Foreign Power Company to relinquish control of its electric plants; confiscations occurred in Colombia and Argentina. By I960, national oil companies in Latin America operated in Colombia, Peru. Uruguay. Venezuela. Argentina, Bolivia. Chile, and Mexico.2y A stiff and ill-wind blew into the face of the international energy companies. The post World War II oil boom Into the 1960s American and British commentators on oil affairs wrote with exuberant optimism of the fantastic upsurge in oil consumption and of the performance of the oil companies in filling that demand. Observers were particularly attentive to the benefits bestowed by the MNOCs upon the producing nations in the form of wages and social and welfare services. This positive appraisal was dampened only by an amorphous fear of Russian aggression in the Middle East and distrust of producing government intentions regarding concessionary terms.30 Non-westerners penned less charitable assessments of western and MNOC policies in the Middle East, questioning their motives and their performance and accusing them of ignorance of and indifference to the aspirations of producing states.31 To such criticisms, the MNOCs responded by emphasizing the sanctity of contracts, the Russian menace, and the inability of host states to manage an industry as complicated as oil. For a time after World War II, the industry's impressive growth deflected criticism. Global withdrawals more than doubled from 1945 to 1955 and almost doubled again by 1965 (Table 4.6). As Table 4.2 demonstrates, oil ruled global energy exchanges after the war. The 53 percent of total oil production exported in 1960 equaled 87 percent of total energy exports and was accompanied by a dramatic transformation in national roles. Oil production in the USA declined from 52 percent of world output in 1950 to under 20 percent after 1970. In 1973, the USSR surpassed the USA as the largest producer. US liftings, although rising, were inadequate to domestic demand. Formerly the leading exporter, the USA became a net importer in 1948. By 1960, US exports and imports of oil formed 2 percent and 21 percent, respectively, of the world total. Simultaneously, America's production-reserve ratio fell off again after 1958, following a trend visible since World War I. Oil lifted from the well-worked American fields cost much more per barrel than oil taken from Venezuela or the flush fields of Saudi Arabia or Kuwait. From 1953 to 1962, a $42 billion investment in domestic fields added 4 billion metric tons to reserves; in the Middle East, an investment of $2 billion added over 19 bmt.32 While domestic American producers inveighed against New Deal production regulations, the rising costs of exploration and production, and the competition of cheaper foreign oil, the MNOCs focused their efforts overseas. The average daily output of a Middle Eastern well reached 3,8<-i0 barrels in 1958 compared with 250 in Venezuela and 12 in the USA. Middle Eastern fields produced 28 percent of world 118 Energy in a politically polarized world production in 1965, compared with 7 percent in 1938. Those fields contained 61 percent of world proven reserves. Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, Iran, and Iraq, each the preserve of a consortium of MNOCs, led the way (Table 4.6). exporting, in 1960, 233 mmt of oil, or just over one-half of all oil moving in international trade.33 Venezuela reigned as the premier oil producer in Latin America, with Mexico a distant second (Table 4.6). Venezuela produced 80 percent of Latin American oil in 1960 and accounted for over 90 percent of regional exports, a large portion in the form of crude transfers to refineries in Aruba and Curacao. Regional demand for oil was far greater in Latin America than in the Middle East; thus a rising proportion of oil remained in the region after World War II. The most marked trend, however, was the growing global marginality of Latin American oil. Between 1950 and 1960, the volume of Venezuelan oil entering the USA rose by over 8 mmt, but the share fell from 69 percent to 51 percent. The Middle Eastern contribution rose from 21 to 30 percent. The position of Venezuela in the US market suffered further attenuation in subsequent years. In Europe and Latin America, competition from cheaper Middle Eastern oil steadily eroded Venezuelan sales during the 1950s and thereafter. Within the region, oil producing but importing nations such as Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico strove to reduce oil imports by developing production capacity. Only marginally successful, they shifted from Venezuela to the Middle East for oil. Brazil, by 1960 the region's largest importer, trimmed its purchases from Venezuela by 25 percent during the 1960s while quadrupling its imports from the Middle East. The shift away from Venezuela intensified during the 1970s.34 Following World War I, an outraged western oil industry had watched helplessly as the Soviet Union nationalized its oil industry, refused to compensate former owners, and revitalized the industry in the face of invasion, civil war, and boycotts. Soviet oil production plummeted during World War II but recovered quickly, increasing by 3.4 times from 1945 to 1955 and more than doubling again by 1960 (Tables 2.7 and 4.6). New fields discovered in the Volga-Urals region and developed at great expense supplied 58 percent of total production in 1955 and 71 percent in 1965. Pushing further east into the incredibly difficult topography of the Siberian and Central Asian fields challenged the technological capabilities of the nation during the 1980s. Despite severe obstacles, Soviet exploratory drilling, accounting for some one-third of total oil industry investment, added substantially to Soviet reserves. By 1983. Russia held three times the reserves of the USA and 13 percent of world reserves.35 The reappearance of Russian oil in western European markets in the 1950s, reflecting production successes and foreign ex- The post World War II oil boom 119 change needs, caused consternation within some circles of NATO. What were Soviet intentions? The multinational oil companies In 1965. western Europe, the USA, and Japan purchased two-thirds of the $17.9 billion in mineral fuels entering world markets, receiving 598 mmt of oil compared with 191 mmt in 1955. OPEC members sold 51 percent of the value of fuel. Fully integrated MNOCs produced, refined, and marketed virtually all of the oil sold by OPEC states and others, excepting the USSR.36 The eight firms appearing in Table 4.7 lifted some 165 mmt in 1950, a volume constituting 85 percent of world producton, excluding the USA, Canada, the Soviet bloc, and China, and 100 percent of Middle Eastern, Indonesian, and Venezuelan production. Table 4.7 summarizes the non-US production and refining shares of the MNOCs. Although their portion gradually narrowed, the MNOCs retained a strong predominance. SONJ produced 74 mmt in 1950 (14 percent of world total) of which 50 mmt originated outside of the USA. SONJ's global share equaled 13 percent in 1965. SONJ, BP, and RDS produced 71 percent of non-US oil in 1950 and 56 percent in 1966 while the remaining five listed in Table 4.7 withdrew 23 percent in 1950 and 44 percent in 1966. As of the late 1950s, these MNOCs sat on 92 percent of proven reserves, owned 75 percent of world refining capacity, and marketed over 70 percent of oil products. The MNOCs retained the organizational configuration described earlier, adding to it as units were created to reflect entry into new concessions or marketing areas.37 The MNOCs listed on Table 4.7 wielded enormous financial strength, owning almost 40 percent of world fixed assets in petroleum of $97.2 billion in 1960, of which SONJ accounted for $10.6 billion. While SONJ's share of global fixed assets declined, the value of its holdings doubled from 1950 to 1960. To the assets of these giants could be added those of five additional firms, four of which were American — Standard Oil of Indiana, Phillips Petroleum, Continental Oil Co., and Marathon Oil Co. —and one. Petrofina, a Belgian firm. Together these five possessed assets worth $10.1 billion in 1%6. $3 billion less than SONJ reported for that datc.w Investments in the petroleum industry soared after World War II (see Table 3.8 for US direct investments abroad). Annual total investments of $2.7 billion in 1946 reached $8.2 billion in 1955, for a ten-year total of $56.2 billion, of which the US oil industry received $38.1 billion. US direct investments abroad from 1946 to 1960 rose from $7.2 billion to 120 Energy in a politically polarized world The post World War II oil boom 121 35 7 ~ V X 2 ~ < £ £ >! ? 8- C O. •2 y a o 5 E S? TO ^■5 ll •s ,? 5 "a ■Si , TO TO y « &■ 0 s - tu 1 E ^ ts C3 " I"! i- 0O < on ^5 . 3 to on « E so Jo a I "a r-' g; O o E c 2 c = a. ^ < >. $31.8 billion with petroleum's portion climbing from 15 to 34 percent and reaching $10.8 biMion in 1960. Then, from 1955 to 1970, the industry invested some $215 billion in the search for and marketing of oil. The share devoted to production in the USA fell off sharply in response to more lucrative opportunities elsewhere. The investments of individual MNOCs cannot be tabulated but reference to capital expenditures hints at their magnitude. From 1950 to 1966, SONJ's capital expenditures totaled $13.9 billion out of a net income of $21.8 billion. Standard's income-expenditure ratio averaged 0.63 over that period, reflecting its self-financing capability and its low long-term debt, a characteristic of other giant oil companies as well. In 1960, the firms listed in Table 4.7 provided 30 percent of a total global oil investment of $10.8 billion.39 Suffocation by numbers? Perhaps! But such figures, at the least, capture the essence of aggregate and individual Big Eight dominance. Few observers, excepting oil industry officials and inveterate advocates of giant enterprise, perceived such control of the industry as a natural consequence of economies of scale and as a boon to consumers.40 Adelman, Al-Otaiba, Leeman, Luciani, Odell, Penrose, among others, each specified the political and institutional forces that permitted the evolution of such concentrations of power in the oil industry.41 Historically, the early concessions in Latin America and the Middle East resulted from the application of overwhelming US and European economic and political pressure on the weak governments in those areas. Ruling cliques in Turkey and Persia (and then Iraq and Iran), Saudi Arabia, Venezuela, and Mexico, entranced by visions of immense royalties and other payments, turned the national patrimony over to foreigners on terms wholly favorable to the MNOCs. Furthermore, western governments deliberately fostered the emergence of such giant firms as AIOC and RDS. In the USA, anti-trust legislation and occasional anti-trust indictments failed to retard industrial concentration at home or abroad. Rarely were American MNOCs inconvenienced by anti-trust proceedings. In an oblique way, then, the US government fostered the evolution of the highly concentrated structure of the post World War II oil industry. Into the 1950s. Big Eight concessions in the Persian Gulf encompassed the entire producing area with the on!v significant deviation