S Further Click here to view this article's online features: • Download figures as PPT slides • Navigate linked references • Download citations • Explore related articles • Search keywords Understanding the Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis Jeffiy Frieden1 and Stefanie Walter2 department of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138; email: jfrieden@harvard.edu 2Department of Political Science, University of Zurich, CH-8050 Zurich, Switzerland; email: walter@ipz.uzh.ch Annu. Rev. Polit. Sei. 2017. 20:371-90 The Annual Review of Political Science is online at polisci.annualreviews.org https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-polisci-051215-023101 Copyright © 2017 by Annual Reviews. All rights reserved Keywords euro, debt crisis, balance-of-payments crisis, distributive conflict, European Monetary Union, austerity Abstract The Eurozone crisis constitutes a grave challenge to European integration. This article presents an overview of the causes of the crisis and analyzes why it has been so difficult to resolve. We focus on how responses to the crisis were shaped by distributive conflicts both among and within countries. On the international level, debtor and creditor countries have fought over the distribution of responsibility for the accumulated debt; countries with current account surpluses and deficits have fought over who should implement the policies necessary to reduce the current account imbalances. Within countries, interest groups have fought to shift the costs of crisis resolution away from themselves. The article emphasizes that the Eurozone crisis shares many features of previous debt and balance-of-payments crises. However, the Eurozone's predicament is unique because it is set within a monetary union that strongly constrains the policy options available to policy makers and vastly increases the interdependence of the euro crisis countries. The outcome of the crisis has also been highly unusual because the costs of crisis resolution have been borne almost exclusively by the debtor countries and taxpayers in the Eurozone. 31i INTRODUCTION On January 1, 1999, eleven member states of the European Union triumphantly introduced a single currency, the euro. The Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) capped 40 years of efforts to create a single market in which goods, capital, and people could move freely. With a common currency, that movement was powerfully facilitated. Ten years after its introduction, the leaders of the Eurozone—now increased to 15 members, with four more waiting to enter—celebrated what appeared to be the successful launch of a new European currency. But within a year after the proud celebration of the euro's tenth anniversary, the Eurozone was thrown into crisis. And the Eurozone crisis has, over the subsequent years, turned into one of the gravest crises in the history of European integration, rivaled only by Britain's 2016 vote to leave the European Union. It took nine years for the Eurozone simply to return to precrisis levels of per capita output. Why did this crisis emerge, and why has it been so difficult to resolve? This article aims to answer these questions. It first analyzes the causes of the crisis and then focuses on how the responses were shaped by distributive conflicts at both the international and national levels. The article emphasizes three main points. First, the Eurozone crisis is just one in a long series of debt and balance-of-payments (BOP) problems that the world has experienced in the past 200 years. Like all of these crises, the Eurozone crisis has led to stark political conflicts about its resolution, both between and within states (e.g., Dyson 2014, Frieden 1991, Pepinsky 2009, Simmons 1994, Walter 2013). Debtor and creditor countries fight over the distribution of responsibility for the accumulated debt; countries with current account surpluses and deficits fight over who should implement the policies necessary to reduce the current account imbalances. Within countries, interest groups fight to shift the costs of crisis resolution away from themselves. The issue at stake, in the Eurozone as so often elsewhere, has been who would bear the burden of adjustment: who would make the sacrifices necessary to clean up the mess of accumulated bad debts (Frieden 2015a). These similarities between the Eurozone crisis and previous crises allow us to analyze its political economy with tools that have been honed in Latin America, Asia, and other parts of the world (Copelovitch et al. 2016). Second, for all these similarities, the Eurozone's predicament is unique. Not only is this a debt crisis among developed countries, which has not happened since Germany in the 1930s,1 but this crisis has taken place in the unique setting of EMU, which involves a wide range of economic and political relations among members of a single market and a common currency. This strongly constrains the policy options available to policy makers and vastly increases the interdependence of the euro crisis countries. At the same time, the centrality of Europe's monetary union to the development of the European Union makes a lasting resolution of the Eurozone crisis crucial to prospects for the future of European integration more generally. Nonetheless, although there has been more institutional reform at the European level than one would have thought possible at the outset of the crisis, these reforms have done little to resolve the Eurozone's root problems. Third, despite the Eurozone countries' high level of interdependence, the political conflicts about sharing the burden of adjustment in the crisis have played themselves out in unusual ways. One set of countries, the creditor states, have been exceptionally successful in shifting most of that burden onto the debtor states. It is not surprising that the Eurozone debt crisis has led to huge bailout programs combined with strong conditionality that have forced the crisis countries to implement harsh austerity measures (e.g., spending cuts and tax increases) and pushed those 1 Industrial countries have resources at their disposal that developing countries do not: stronger financial systems, better social safety nets, more established creditworthiness. So the parallels between Spain and, say, Argentina are strong but not perfect. Frieden • Walter countries into deep recessions; this is a commonplace of debt crises. But it is striking—and extremely unusual—that the creditors have not granted the debtor countries (with the exception of Greece and Cyprus) any significant debt relief or debt restructuring and that the burden of crisis resolution has been pushed almost entirely onto the shoulders of taxpayers in both debtor and creditor states. Nevertheless, no country has left the Eurozone so far. CAUSES OF THE EUROZONE CRISIS In its essence, the crisis in the Eurozone is a classic debt and BOP crisis.2 Countries in the Eurozone borrowed heavily, largely to finance current consumption, as financial institutions in the rest of Europe were eager to lend. Large current account imbalances developed, as capital and goods flowed out of countries with current account surpluses into countries with current account deficits. Borrowing fed economic expansion, which grew into a boom, then a bubble, largely in housing markets. When the bubble burst, lending dried up, and the heavily indebted countries found themselves unable to service their debts, unable to make up for the collapse of domestic demand by exporting, and unable to borrow additional funds in order to cover their continuing payments deficits. As with all debt and BOP crises, the result was economic distress and political conflict. In this section, we provide an overview of the origins of the crisis. The discussion parallels the view presented by Baldwin et al. (2015) of the now generally accepted consensus among economists about the economic causes of the crisis. Macroeconomic Divergence and Capital Flows with a Single Currency In the late 1990s, EMU was completed and the euro came into existence. By definition, the monetary authorities of a single currency area—including a nation-state—must adopt a single monetary policy. This can be economically and politically difficult when different regions, and different groups within regions, face different conditions (Mundell 1961). At the time of the creation of the Eurozone, there were major divergences among the macroeconomic circumstances of its constituent states. These countries varied significantly with regard to growth and inflation, as well as in their institutional configurations and growth models (e.g., Hall & Franzese 1998, Iversen et al. 2016, Johnston et al. 2014, Nolke 2016). The experiences of Germany and Spain are typical. Between 1998 and 2007, inflation in Germany averaged 1.5% a year, compared to 3.2% in Spain. Over the decade this led to a substantial divergence in prices. Moreover, German labor-market institutions led to wage restraint, which was not the case in Spain, so that wages diverged even more; in those ten years, unit labor costs in Germany fell by 3.9% while in Spain they rose by 30.4% (Frieden 2015a, ch. 4). The European Central Bank (ECB) had to devise one monetary policy despite this divergence in national economic conditions. Not surprisingly, it tended to choose an interest rate somewhere between what would have been ideal for slow-growing countries such as Finland, Germany, France, Benelux, and Austria and what would have been preferred by the fast-growing periphery in Ireland and Southern Europe. This interest rate did little to combat slow growth in the core, where domestic investment opportunities were limited, and created strong incentives to invest abroad both in the Eurozone and outside it. At the same time, low or negative real interest rates in the periphery gave these countries substantial incentives to borrow. 2 The two are roughly identical because a country running a balance-of-payments deficit is accumulating debts. The payments balance is a measure of flows; debts are a measure of stocks. www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis cd II -o tj o Ö <1 oo o on £ .d 'S ä 'S 3 £ 0 5 Average deficit (%) Figure 1 Average current account deficits in the Eurozone (as percentage of gross domestic product), 2003-2009. The difference in underlying conditions thus interacted with monetary policy to encourage capital flows. Almost immediately, financial institutions in slow-growing northern European countries searched for higher-yielding opportunities in the more rapidly growing periphery in Central, Eastern, and Southern Europe, and capital began flowing from the North to the periphery. Most of the loans ended up going into the periphery's expanding housing market and the related construction industries. In Portugal, and especially in Greece, the government also took advantage of rock-bottom interest rates to finance growing public deficits. The process was self-reinforcing: The more capital flowed into countries like Spain and Ireland, the faster they grew; the more asset prices there rose, the more attractive they looked to lenders, drawing in still more capital (for overviews, see, e.g., Lane 2012, Wihlborg et al. 2010). Borrowers and lenders fed an upward spiral, with capital flows driving expansion and expansion encouraging further capital flows. The result was first a boom, then a bubble, primarily in housing but in asset markets more generally. At the same time, unit labor costs and real effective exchange rates rose significantly, eroding competitiveness especially vis-á-vis the core economies, where wage bargaining institutions allowed for wage moderation (Johnston et al. 2014, Hópner & Luttner 2017). As a result, large current account surpluses in the core and similarly large current account deficits in the periphery emerged (see Figure 1). The Eurozone experience thus had all the features of a classic capital-flow cycle. Bailout Expectations These dynamics were further fueled by investors' expectation that, in the event of a crisis in one of the debtor states, the other member states would be forced to intervene. It was clear 374 Frieden • Walter that contagion from a financial crisis in one country would be extremely rapid, and potentially extremely damaging, within a common currency area. The expectation was that EMU made each member state "too connected to fail," so a country in financial distress would be bailed out. Governments understood that this bailout problem created moral hazard. The knowledge that the other states would be likely to bail out a country in financial problems could induce reckless behavior, which in turn might in fact make a bailout necessary. Faced with the prospect of this moral hazard, the founding governments of the Eurozone declared that there would be no bailout. However, this declaration rang hollow. It was not enough simply to say that there would not be a bailout, for investors and other observers had long experience with governments being forced into bailouts against their will and better judgment. What could, and should, have been done was to design an institutional structure to deal with financial difficulties in one member state: a highly conditional fund patterned on the International Monetary Fund (FMF), a plan to wind up troubled banks, a mechanism to restructure debts. But some of the principal member states seemed to believe that any discussion of ways to deal with a financial crisis would only stimulate fears, and so the member states never considered a strategy more pragmatic and realistic than simply saying "No" over and over. The result was that the "no-bailout" commitment was not credible. Bailout expectations meant that even the least creditworthy member states were able to borrow at rates roughly equivalent to those charged to Germany (Chang & Leblond 2015). This was especially striking in the case of Greece, which joined the Eurozone in 2001. No sensible observer regarded Greece as a credit risk equivalent to Germany; but the expectation was that if Greece got into trouble, Germany and other more creditworthy member states would bail it out. And, of course, the ability of the Greek government to borrow at unprecedentedly low interest rates gave the government major incentives to borrow far more than was prudent. Inadequate Policy Responses European policy makers could have responded to the build-up of these imbalances by implementing appropriate fiscal policies. Germany and other northern European countries could have stimulated domestic economic growth, and absorbed more of their own savings, with an expansionary fiscal policy of tax cuts and spending increases. This would have reduced their current account surpluses and kept more capital at home. Similarly, the peripheral European countries could have counteracted the slippery slope to a boom and bubble with more restrictive fiscal policies. Portugal and Greece were running government budget deficits, and they certainly could have dampened the irrational exuberance with tax increases and spending cuts. The Spanish and Irish government budgets were balanced, but the logic of counter-cyclical fiscal policy would have dictated that they accumulate surpluses—again, raising taxes and cutting spending—so as to restrain their overheated economies. However, there was little or no national interest in adopting the appropriate counter-cyclical fiscal policies—in fact, fiscal policies became more procyclical after the euro was introduced (Benetrix & Lane 2013). Germans appeared perfectly happy to see their financial institutions lend wildly to the European periphery, even while they maintained their traditional fiscal conservatism at home. Spaniards and others in the fast-growing periphery had no interest in reducing the pace of economic growth. The principal argument for altering national fiscal policies was that it would help stabilize the Eurozone as a whole; but no nation's politicians, or public, seemed concerned about the Eurozone as a whole, focusing instead on domestic matters. In other words, for fiscal policies to have their full effect, member-state governments would have had to cooperate in designing and www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis implementing them in the interests of a common purpose; and there was little or no political support for altering national policies in order to serve a vague Eurozone-wide common purpose. Attempts to coordinate fiscal policies at the EU level through the Stability and Growth Pact also largely failed (Alt et al. 2014, Baerg & Hallerberg 2016). As a result, fiscal policies remained uncoordinated, and indeed exacerbated the underlying macroeconomic imbalances (Lane 2012). This was not solely a Eurozone phenomenon. The United States and the United Kingdom, for example, also experienced large-scale capital inflows that led to rapid increases in the price of assets, especially housing, eventually leading to a housing bubble. In that sense, the process in the Eurozone was simply a microcosm of what was happening elsewhere. But EMU made a difference. One main difference was that the non-Eurozone countries that were undergoing this capital-flow cycle had full independence to design their own monetary policies, including the ability to devalue the exchange rate, an ability that proved particularly important when the bubble burst. Another was that they were less interconnected, and a third was that their fiscal policies produced fewer externalities than in the Eurozone. These features reflected gaps in the original design and implementation of EMU. They were widely understood at the time, and observers on both sides of the Atlantic warned that they would need to be addressed (for an overview, see Jonung & Drea 2010). It was well understood that the ECB would have trouble designing one monetary policy for such a disparate set of countries, and that the absence of fiscal policy coordination would cause problems. And the central issue of bailout expectations—and of the lack of credibility of the no-bailout commitment—was also generally understood (e.g., Frieden 1998). But attempts to address these issues collided, over and over, with domestic and international political realities that militated against their resolution. No government was willing to alter its policies enough to deal with the systemic dangers that were building up in the Eurozone. And so as lending grew, the borrowing economies expanded, and asset and housing prices rose, neither national governments nor the institutions of the European Union and the Eurozone were able to address the stresses and strains that informed observers knew were building up. The Bubble Bursts: How a Private Debt Crisis Turned into a Sovereign Debt Crisis The global financial crisis that began late in 2007 brought the merry-go-round to an end. Peripheral European nations faced a "sudden stop." The lending spigot was shut, and the borrowing nations were left with massive debts, a collapse in housing and other asset prices, and a terrible recession. It was soon clear that the continent's financial system was saddled with trillions of euros in debts that were very unlikely to be serviced as originally contracted, presenting a serious threat to the health of financial institutions that had been lending. Without direct intervention, European finance was likely to collapse. The Eurozone crisis began in earnest when, in late 2009, the Greek government disclosed that Greece had lied about its public deficit for years, and disclosed a budget deficit much larger than had previously been reported (for a chronology of the crisis, see, e.g., Copelovitch et al. 2016). Spreads on Greek bonds surged, and soon the Greek government found itself unable to service its debt. A few months later, a bailout package was put together to help Greece weather the crisis—and then a second package. Financial markets, it turned out, had been right to doubt the "no-bailout" commitment. Whereas the Greek crisis was a genuine sovereign debt crisis, it is important to understand that the crisis in most other Eurozone countries did not result from government borrowing (Blyth 2013). In fact, at its outset, the crisis was mainly one of private loans to private borrowers—a Frieden • Walter private debt crisis and not a state-to-state issue at all. But as the crisis evolved, it slowly changed into a sovereign debt crisis. It came to implicate national governments at least in part because of the unwillingness or inability of debtor and creditor governments to force "their" private financial institutions to bear the full costs of their mistakes. Two things contributed to this evolution. The first was the general concern that problems in one nation's private sector could affect general economic conditions in the country as a whole. This commonplace view gives governments reasons to be concerned about private financial difficulties, as a loss of confidence in the banking system can lead to a more generalized loss of confidence in the economy. Despite the private-to-private nature of the vast majority of the loans when the crisis hit, problems would inevitably affect general economic conditions and thus were of concern to national governments. A second development was crucial in turning a private debt problem into a major issue among governments. As debts went bad in the debtor nations, debtor-country banks risked illiquidity and insolvency. To prevent a financial meltdown, governments ended up assuming many of the bad debts of their banks—converting private into sovereign debts. But this led to growing public debt, which increased the country's sovereign credit risk, which further weakened the financial system, and thus created a negative bank-sovereign loop (Acharya et al. 2014). In Spain, for example, the government stepped in to nationalize or bail out its troubled banks, in the process borrowing heavily to finance the bailouts. Financial institutions in the creditor nations similarly faced collapse as their debts went unserviced, leading governments to devise means to support their financial sectors. Whether this socializing of losses was due to the fear that inaction would have caused major economic disruptions or to the desire to shore up economically and politically important private banks, it should be clear that both debtor and creditor governments chose to shunt the costs of the crisis almost entirely onto the backs of taxpayers. With peripheral governments now heavily in debt to creditor governments, and more broadly to other Eurozone member states and to Eurozone and EU institutions, the intra-European politics of the debt crisis became particularly troubled (Mabbett & Schelkle 2015). As always, the core question was which countries would bear the principal costs of dealing with the accumulated debts: how the adjustment burden would be distributed (Dyson 2014, Frieden 2015b). CRISIS RESOLUTION: OPTIONS PRESENTED, CHOICES MADE The main issue of contention in debt crises is how to deal with accumulated bad debts. One option is for debtor countries to repay the outstanding debt, mobilizing domestic resources by cutting spending or increasing taxes. Another option is for creditor countries to grant debt restructuring, providing some relief to debtor countries. Creditors want to be paid back in full, or as close to that as possible, whereas debtors want their debts to be restructured and reduced to the largest extent possible. Both sides have bargaining chips, as creditors threaten to block future access to credit and debtors threaten to stop payment. This is why in most debt crises, creditors and debtors share the debt burden, although the precise terms vary. Debt crises are closely related to BOP crises. The resolution of debt crises concentrates on the stock of accumulated debts, whereas the resolution of BOP problems focuses on economic adjustments to address the flow problem of continuing current account imbalances that fuel the debt problems. BOP deficits imply that the country imports both more goods and more capital than it exports, which means that current account deficits are associated with rising external debt levels. Not surprisingly, all the main Eurozone crisis countries ran sizeable current account deficits in the years before the crisis (see Figure 1). Thus, to resolve a debt crisis, debtor countries not only have to resolve the problem of accumulated debts but typically also have to turn their current www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis Table 1 Options for resolving balance-of-payments (BOP) imbalances External adjustment Internal adjustment Financing Deficit country Exchange-rate devaluation Austerity and structural reforms Cover funding gap through external funding Surplus country Exchange-rate appreciation Inflation and reforms aimed at boosting domestic demand Provide financing for deficit countries with BOP problems Implication for the Eurozone Eurozone breakup Convergence of deficit and surplus countries Permanent financing structures (e.g., fiscal federalism, automatic stabilizers) account deficit into a surplus, to start exporting more goods and services than they import in order to earn the funds needed to repay the accumulated debts (the alternative is, of course, to default or restructure those debts). Likewise, creditor states can contribute to resolving these crises by boosting domestic demand to reduce their current account surplus. Policy makers have several policy choices at hand when it comes to resolving the flow problem of BOP imbalances (Broz et al. 2016, Walter 2013). The necessary policy adjustment can occur in both surplus and deficit countries, in an externally or internally oriented way; and adjustment can be avoided altogether if the current account deficit is financed by external sources of money instead (see Table 1). The first option for rebalancing the current account, external adjustment, involves a change of the country's exchange rate. This has been the standard response for deficit countries in the past. By devaluing its currency, a deficit country can make its domestic products more competitive, which reduces imports and stimulates exports. A surplus country can revalue its currency, making domestic products more expensive relative to foreign products, thereby increasing imports and reducing exports. The second option, internal adjustment, means that relative prices are adjusted through domestic macroeconomic policy changes and structural reforms. For deficit countries, this strategy is also known as internal devaluation, and it implies austerity policies such as public spending cuts and tax increases, as well as structural reforms that increase competitiveness. Because these measures aim at a reduction of domestic demand and a deflation of domestic prices, they are typically associated with increased unemployment, lower wages, asset price deflation, and recession. For surplus countries, internal adjustment implies policies that increase relative prices—for example, through loose monetary or fiscal policy or through reforms that stimulate domestic demand and increase inflation. Both internal and external adjustment can be painful and costly for policy makers. Devaluations often cost policy makers their jobs (Frankel 2005), and recessions reduce politicians' reelection chances. Policy makers therefore frequently resort to a third option: financing the current account deficit. Initially, deficit countries often respond to BOP pressures by drawing on their foreign currency reserves. When these dry up, they need external support. Surplus countries, which tend to be the creditors of deficit countries, are often willing to grant such support, either bilaterally or through international organizations such as the IMF, because it not only reduces the risk that a deficit country defaults on its debt but also allows surplus countries to forgo adjustment at home. But the financing strategy has one important downside: It does not resolve the underlying structural BOP imbalances, and often aggravates them, so this approach carries the risk that eventual adjustment will have to be more extensive than if it had been implemented early on (Frankel & Wei 2004). Debt and BOP crises thus confront policy makers with a list of unattractive options. Different socioeconomic groups, and, at the aggregate level, different societies differ in the extent to which 37$ Frieden • Walter they are vulnerable to each of these options. It should therefore come as no surprise that distributive concerns—both within countries and among countries—always influence the politics of resolving debt and BOP crises. What does this mean for the politics of the euro crisis? In principle, these three policy options exist in the euro crisis as well. But because the debt and BOP crises occurred within a currency union, crisis resolution has proven very difficult, and the Eurozone's policy response is unusual in a number of respects. In essence, Europeans have opted for a strategy that mainly relies on debt repayment by and internal adjustment in debtor states, coupled with temporary financing and expansionary monetary policy.3 Large bailout programs have been set up, but crisis countries have been forced to implement austerity and reforms in return, and no meaningful debt relief has been granted. On the one hand, this choice of crisis response—a combination of internal adjustment and financing rather than external adjustment and default—is not surprising. In the context of Europe's EMU, external adjustment implies a breakup of the Eurozone. Different variants of such a breakup are thinkable, ranging from the exit of a single country to the formation of two or more currency blocs or the introduction of parallel currencies. But whatever its form, external adjustment would mean that the euro would cease to exist in its current form, and this would carry huge costs for everyone involved. For this reason, this adjustment path has so far been ruled out by virtually all Eurozone policy makers. Removing external adjustment from its menu of options, the Eurozone is left with the alternatives of internal adjustment and financing. What is more surprising is the willingness of the debtor countries to accept the creditors' refusal to grant debt relief and their insistence that they should shoulder the burden of internal adjustment almost entirely. This has resulted in deep recessions and record levels of unemployment in the debtor countries, while creditor countries have been much less affected by the crisis. The costs of the crisis have hence been very unequally distributed among the countries of the Eurozone. And inequality with regard to burden sharing does not end at the international level: The costs of crisis resolution have also been very unequally distributed within countries, where some groups have been much harder hit than others. It is therefore not surprising that there has been a great deal of conflict both among and within countries. Coming on top of the complex political structure of the European Union, and the high level of uncertainty regarding the viability of different policy options, these conflicts have resulted in the Eurozone's piecemeal approach to addressing the crisis and help explain why many key issues still remain unresolved. CRISIS RESOLUTION AT THE EUROPEAN LEVEL: CONFLICT AMONG COUNTRIES Debt and BOP crises typically give rise to conflict between creditor and debtor countries, and the Eurozone crisis has been no exception. Creditors and debtors have squared off over how to address the enormous stock of accumulated debts; surplus and deficit countries have argued over who should be doing the adjusting. In the case of the Eurozone debts, interstate conflict was complicated by the fact that private debts were quickly assumed by the governments of both debtor and creditor nations, and by European institutions more generally. Of course, this threw every interaction between debtor and creditor governments into the cauldron of intra-European 3 For simplicity, we mostly refer to debtor and creditor states in the discussion that follows. But it is important to keep in mind that a debtor state starts from a position as a deficit state, whereas a creditor state usually starts from a position as a surplus country. www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis politics, pitting national governments with divergent interests against one another. Indeed, from the moment the crisis began, debtor and creditor states have jockeyed for position in this difficult bargaining interaction (Schimmelfennig 2015), leveraging both bargaining power and (mostly self-serving) ideas in the process (Bulmer 2014, Dyson 2010). Although they agreed that external adjustment—some form of Eurozone breakup—was not an option, they agreed on little else. Conflicts About How to Share the Adjustment Burden Virtually all debt crises end with some form of compromise because both sides in these conflicts have weapons: Creditors threaten to block future access to credit, debtors threaten to stop payment. Creditors typically hold most of the bargaining chips, for the threat of freezing errant debtors out of credit markets is both credible and powerful. But debtors can and do threaten to default, which can cause damage to creditor financial markets. In the case of the Eurozone crisis, both sides have had additional weapons. Creditors threatened errant debtor states with expulsion from the European Union or the Eurozone, although the legal basis for this was unclear. Debtors, for their part, knew that if one member state defaulted there was likely to be a panic on bond markets that would affect all member states—including the creditors. This makes it all the more striking that the member states, and the institutions of the Eurozone, have shied away from what is the most common response to a debt crisis, debt restructuring. Although there has been some debt restructuring in the cases of Greece and Cyprus,4 there has been none in Spain, Portugal, and Ireland. There have been financial rescue packages to help debtor governments meet their obligations in the midst of massive recessions, but there has been no meaningful debt relief. This is extraordinary, because virtually all debt crises eventually lead to some form of debt relief, just as corporate bankruptcies lead to a restructuring of the bankrupt company's liabilities. As with corporate bankruptcies, it is widely recognized that debt relief can be beneficial to both debtors and creditors, inasmuch as it puts troubled debts on a sounder footing. Debt restructuring, indeed, is widely regarded as a very common Pareto improvement. To be sure, it is not uncommon for the principal adjustment burden to fall on the debtor countries. But the absence of any real debt relief for the three principal Eurozone debtors makes this crisis extremely unusual—perhaps even unique—among sovereign debt crises. Pressure from creditor countries has also, as is often the case, taken the form of insistence that the debtors undertake substantial structural reforms in order to address chronic BOP problems (Copelovitch & Enderlein 2016, Hall 2012). But countries like Spain and Ireland are not developing countries, and pressures from creditors have led these countries to predominantly rely on austerity rather than on significant reforms of social policies or labor market institutions.5 The effect of this strategy on economic growth and employment prospects in these countries has been harsh. As a result, in the Eurozone crisis, the burden of adjustment has been put almost exclusively on the shoulders of the debtor countries. Figure 2 illustrates howunequally the costs of the adjustment have been spread across Eurozone countries. It shows how different Eurozone countries have fared throughout the crisis, tracing their economic development between 2007 and 2013. The five main Eurozone debtor countries—Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and especially Spain and Greece—have witnessed massive increases in unemployment. In 2013, GDP had fallen back to the levels of when 4Greece's debt was so enormous that it was clear almost from the start that it could never be serviced, so significant portions of that country's debt have been restructured. In Cyprus, debt restructuring was one of the conditions attached to a bailout package from the Troika. 5 Indeed, it has also been difficult to take creditor countries' insistence on structural reforms seriously when so many of the creditor countries have been unable or unwilling to carry them out themselves. Frieden • Walter Ol Ol Ol 160 150 ™ — 140 £ S Q Ii 130 O Ol — Ol «Ol 120 .2 ~ 110 o g 100 2007 2013 -■ Creditor countries -• Debtor countries ■• Ireland Figure 2 10 20 Unemployment (% of total labor force) Crisis cost for selected Eurozone countries. Economic development between 2007 (start of data line) and 2013 (square or circle) is shown. Abbreviation: GDP, gross domestic product. Source: World Bank. the Eurozone was founded in three of these countries, and GDP had decreased significantly in all five debtor states. In contrast, the economic cost of the crisis has been much smaller or even nonexistent in the creditor states. Several reasons can be adduced for the fact that the principal burden of adjustment to the Eurozone crisis has fallen on the debtors. The first is, as mentioned, the general fact that creditors have a powerful weapon, the threat of financial exclusion. This threat is particularly serious for European countries, which are tightly integrated into European financial markets, and for which exclusion from those markets would be very damaging. A second consideration in the Eurozone case is that creditors have also invoked the requirements of broader EU and Eurozone membership, implying—sometimes stating—that less than full repayment could result in expulsion from the Eurozone or the European Union. Third, whether the threat of expulsion is real or not, certainly the extent of financial and commercial integration among EU members is so high that any loss of credibility on the part of the government and firms of one nation could be extremely costly. This last factor helps explain why many in the debtor countries have in fact been reluctant to press the issue, for fear that it might affect their own economic relations with the rest of the Eurozone. Fourth, the Eurozone creditors used their political influence over the IMF to force it to ignore its own rules, which would have required substantial debt restructuring (IEO 2016). This eliminated the possibility that the involvement of the IMF—a repository of decades of experience in dealing with debt crises—would be objective and even-handed.6 Finally, emphasizing ordo-liberal ideas, creditor countries have been successful in framing the crisis in ways that suggest that deficit countries caused it and hence should resolve it (Blyth 2013). Conflicts About How to Reform the Eurozone The crisis has also led to some attempts to rework the Eurozone itself (Niemann & Ioannou2015). The member states have devised a series of Eurozone-wide mechanisms to attempt to address 6The report of the IMF's own Independent Evaluation Office (IEO 2016) makes this very clear. The role of political pressure from creditor countries is mentioned, for example, on p. 42. www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis the fallout of the crisis and avoid a recurrence. Every step of the way has been controversial (Howarth & Quaglia 2015). Efforts at greater fiscal policy coordination have been extremely limited and have had little impact. Instead, attempts to confront the crisis have centered on monetary policy, although the ECB implemented expansionary policies much later than its US and British counterparts. The member states also agreed to a banking union that centralizes and harmonizes a great deal of financial regulation under the auspices of the ECB (Howarth & Quaglia 2014). Perhaps the most important such institutional innovation is the development of a Eurozone bailout fund, the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), to make loans to troubled debtor governments. The process began with the establishment of two temporary funds, the European Financial Stability Facility and the European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism, which provided funds to troubled debtors (Gocaj & Meunier 2013). In 2012 the member states agreed on a permanent fund, the ESM, to lend to countries in distress. The ESM was capitalized at €80 billion with a total lending capacity of €700 billion. Access to ESM funds depends on approval by the "troika," which consists of the ECB, the European Commission, and the IMF. A country's use of ESM funds (i.e., a bailout) binds it to carry out macroeconomic and other economic policies designed to address enduring payments imbalances. Although the ESM is relatively new, it is clear that its operation will raise many of the political issues present in debtor-creditor relations more generally. In a sense, the ESM is like a Eurozone IMF, with all that implies. Member states all want such a mechanism, but they disagree fundamentally on what it should require of governments that have recourse to its funds. There have been continuing conflicts over other proposals, both to address the crisis and to try to prevent future crises. One discussion has centered on financing, which could provide a route out of this impasse. If financing were provided in a permanent fashion, adjustment would be needed on a much smaller scale. Permanent financing implies some form of a transfer (or fiscal) union, be it in the form of Eurozone-wide welfare policies, Eurobonds, or direct transfers. One very popular suggestion, put forth by economists and eventually supported by the European Commission, was for Eurozone member states to jointly issue bonds backed by all (see, e.g., De Grauwe & Moesen 2009).7 This would have shared both the risk and the benefits of pooling sovereign borrowing. Although it would clearly have benefited the less creditworthy countries more than the rest, there is some reason to believe that it would have enhanced sovereign debt markets more generally, adding to their depth and liquidity. In the event, the idea was opposed by the German government and has not been pursued. More generally, financing proposals have faced the problem that they are unpopular in both surplus states, which would likely foot the bill, and deficit countries, which would likely see a reduction in their national sovereignty in economic policy making (Streeck & Elsasser 2016). More importantly, such permanent financing schemes would require more political integration than is currently feasible. It is important to recognize that the principal cause of the failure to address the crisis is to be found in the actions of the member states. Certainly the European institutions, with the exception of the ECB, have not helped much. But the real obstacle to a constructive resolution of the crisis is that the national governments simply have not been able to agree on how to move forward. The governments of creditor nations have continued to insist that the debtors must shoulder the adjustment burden, contending that only austerity can bring them out of their deep depressions. The governments of debtor nations have persistently maintained that only some form of debt relief will make the burden bearable. Meaningful negotiations to address the core problem, the Another widely discussed proposal was to create some form of an EMU-wide unemployment insurance regime. Frieden • Walter weight of accumulated debts, have been deadlocked for years, and it is primarily the member states that are responsible for this deadlock. One of the more serious effects of the Eurozone debt crisis, and of the inadequacies of the policy response to the crisis, has been the wedge it has driven among Eurozone member states. Rather than build cohesion among EMU members, the crisis has driven countries into warring camps, each side blaming the other for the crisis and for the extraordinarily slow recovery. Governments in the Eurozone remain at loggerheads over how to address the aftermath of the crisis and how to move forward once it is past (Dyson 2014). The failure of the member states, and of other EU or Eurozone institutions, to address the debt crisis has left the ECB as the principal—practically sole—Eurozone economic institution capable of attempting to address it. The ECB has in fact taken quite aggressive measures, including a substantial bond-buying program to shore up financial markets and a monetary policy that has pushed interest rates into negative territory. The ECB's policies have had some positive impact, especially on confidence in the euro, but the ECB alone was not enough to counteract the massive recessionary impact of the debt overhang. As might be expected, ECB policy has also been controversial. For many in northern Europe, the central bank's low (even negative) interest rate policy is anathema, limiting the returns to their savers. For many in peripheral Europe, the central bank has not done enough to alleviate the impact of the crisis. The ECB has become embroiled in political disputes, something its architects explicitly tried to avoid. Overall, neither the institutions of the European Union nor the constituent member states have effectively addressed the crisis (Jones et al. 2015). There has been no effective coordinated fiscal response, no debt restructuring for any country but Greece and Cyprus, and little substantial reform to national or Eurozone institutions. After years of ongoing problems, the root causes of the crisis are still not resolved. DOMESTIC CRISIS RESOLUTION: POLITICS WITHIN COUNTRIES The euro crisis has also been characterized by strong distributive conflict within countries about how the costs of crisis resolution should be shared. Such conflicts have taken place in both debtor (deficit) and creditor (surplus) states. These conflicts have not been fought as conflicts about the appropriate adjustment strategy but mainly as conflicts about how to implement an internal adjustment strategy (in deficit/debtor countries) and how to provide financing and avoid internal adjustment (in surplus/creditor countries). This is because external adjustment—that is, leaving the euro, forcing one country to leave the euro, or splitting up the Eurozone—has rarely been regarded as a viable option. Support for the euro has remained remarkably high in all Eurozone countries throughout the crisis (Hobolt & Wratil 2015, Roth et al. 2016). Although in deficit states most people express a preference for the highly unrealistic crisis strategy of keeping the euro and ending austerity at the same time (Clements et al. 2014, Fernandez-Albertos & Kuo 2016), they have shown a strong preference for the euro when pressed to choose between the two (Dinas et al. 2016). So far, only populist parties have called for their country to leave the Eurozone or for a dissolution of the Eurozone altogether (Heinen et al. 2015). Among the creditor states, the Dutch Partij voor de Vrijheid, the German Alternative für Deutschland, the French Front National, and the Austrian Freiheitliche Partei Österreichs have called for a controlled dissolution of the Eurozone, with the True Finns in Finland taking a critical but more cautious position. Among the deficit countries, there has been a strong push for a referendum on the euro in Italy, supported by Beppe Grillo's Five Star Movement, the Lega Nord, and Forza Italia; and in Greece, the Communist Party and the leftist splinter group Popular Unity have proposed leaving the euro. www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis But in addition to virtually all nonpopulist parties, there are also two important populist parties who do not support leaving the Eurozone: Podemos in Spain and SYRIZA (Synaspismos Rizospastikis Aristeras) in Greece. Thus, with the external adjustment option off the table—at least for the time being—national political conflicts have centered on how to manage the crisis within the preferred strategy of internal adjustment in deficit states coupled with some financing from surplus states. Crisis Politics in Debtor States Conflict has been most intense in debtor states, which were hit hardest by the crisis. Having ruled out an exit from the Eurozone, they have been tasked to implement internal adjustment: spending cuts, demand compression, structural reforms. As in many other crises, this setting has created political difficulties, distributive conflicts, and turmoil around the question of how the resources necessary to service debts should be mobilized and which policy reforms should be implemented to rebalance the current account. Given that surplus countries have been unwilling to share the burden of adjustment, politics in deficit countries has centered on who will bear the brunt of the costs of the crisis: consumers, taxpayers, investors, government employees, pensioners, the unemployed, the export sector, the nontradable sector, and so on. Although the fallout from the crisis in deficit states has been huge, its impact has varied significantly among social groups. For example, even though overall unemployment and poverty rates have significantly increased across the board, the young have been hit hardest. Youth unemployment tripled in Ireland between 2007 and 2012, and between 2012 and 2014 more than half of economically active people under age 2 5 in Greece and Spain were without work (source: Eurostat 2016, http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database). More specifically, unemployment has hit the young, male, and less educated people hardest (Gutierrez 2014). Likewise, relative poverty rates for young people went up in Italy, Portugal, and especially Spain and Greece. At the same time, relative poverty rates for the elderly declined considerably. Interestingly, inequality has only increased in some countries (most notably, Greece), whereas crisis policies seem to have had no effect or an inequality-decreasing impact in other countries (Matsaganis & Leventi 2014). Both crisis-related policies and the overall impact of the economic crisis in deficit states have thus differed in how they have affected different socioeconomic groups (Avram et al. 2013). More generally, austerity—spending cuts and tax increases—has been the preferred policy choice, whereas structural reforms have been implemented more hesitantly. Given that the latter were often aimed at stripping privileges from politically influential groups, they were often implemented only under considerable external pressure, and even then compliance has been spotty. Similarly, banks and other financial market participants have largely been able to socialize their losses, rolling them over to taxpayers (Blyth 2013). As discussed above, debtor-country governments ended up assuming many of the bad debts of their banks—which converted private into sovereign debts. Entrenched insider-outsider structures (Bentolila et al. 2012), strong resistance by vested interests (Featherstone 2015), and clientelistic politics (Afonso et al. 2015) have thus generally protected politically influential groups. This mirrors earlier crises where governments have shielded their own voter base from the crisis consequences as much as possible (Walter 2016). These conflicts about how to manage the crisis have reshaped party systems in some crisis countries and paralyzed politics in others. Although some of the discontent has played out in the streets (Accornero & Ramos Pinto 2015, Genovese et al. 2016, Giugni & Grasso 2016, Peterson et al. 2015), the electoral consequences of the crisis have been more profound, affecting party systems in Ireland (Marsh & Mikhaylov 2012), Portugal (Goulart & Veiga 2016, Magalhaes 2012), Italy (Bellucci 2014), Spain (Martin & Urquizu-Sancho 2012, Medina & Correa 2016), and Greece (Dinas & Rori 2013, Rori 2016). In Greece, Italy, and Spain, influential populist and Frieden • Walter antiestablishment parties have emerged or been strengthened in the wake of the crisis: SYRIZA in Greece, the Five Star Movement and Lega Nord in Italy, and Podemos and Ciudadanos in Spain. Overall, incumbents and mainstream parties have been punished in elections across the board, and the crisis has had a destabilizing effect on these countries' party systems (Bellucci et al. 2012, Bosco & Verney 2016, Hernandez & Kriesi 2016, Katsanidou & Otjes 2016). Crisis Politics in Creditor States Creditor states have also been internally conflicted about how to resolve the euro crisis, equally grappling with the question of who should bear the main burden. Should financial institutions be made to absorb the losses from the loans they made? Or should taxpayers step in, either to shore up the domestic financial systems or to provide funding to help the debtor countries service their debts? Should surplus countries engage in internal macroeconomic adjustment to boost domestic consumption and hence lower the adjustment burden on deficit states? One of the most important distributive questions that faced creditor states early on was whether they should (a) let their financial system absorb the costs of the crisis by defaults or debt restructuring in the debtor states, or (b) transfer the costs of the crisis onto taxpayers by providing public funds to the debtor countries that would allow them to service their debts. When the question of whether to bail out Greece first arose in 2010, it was clear that the alternative—a Greek default— might trigger similar defaults in other debtor countries, which in turn would seriously threaten the stability of banks in the creditor states still weakened from the global financial storm of2007-2009. Not only could this have triggered a Eurozone-wide financial crisis and seriously damaged the single-currency project, but bank bailouts were also deeply unpopular among publics in creditor countries (Goerres & Walter 2016) and hence politically costly. This made it politically easier to support domestic banks indirectly via a bailout of a Eurozone debtor state (Ardagna & Caselli 2014). Figure 3 shows that this question has been decidedly resolved in favor of domestic banks, which have been able to reduce significantly their exposure to crisis countries over the 2009-2013 period. (The reduction is even more pronounced if one considers exposure to claims on Greece only.) As a result, most of the risks associated with this debt have been passed on to taxpayers in a variety of forms, such as bailout guarantees or growing Target2 balances in creditor states' central banks. In short, creditor countries preferred to finance debtor countries temporarily with taxpayer money, while pushing the internal adjustment burden onto these countries through strict Germany Netherlands Finland France Belgium Figure 3 Bank claims by selected Eurozone countries on Eurozone crisis countries, 2009-2013. Source: Bank for International Settlements (http://www.bis.org/statistics/full_data_sets.htm). www.annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis conditionality and sheltering their own financial institutions from the costs of debt restructuring. Given the exposure of creditors' national banking systems to bad debts in the Eurozone periphery, it is perhaps not surprising that governments were intent on steering the debate away from the issue. They have been successful in framing the crisis as a sovereign debt crisis of overspending in deficit countries, to which the logical solution is austerity in these states (Blyth 2013). Much existing research on crisis politics in creditor states focuses on Germany, where the dominant narrative of the crisis has been one of "northern saints and southern sinners" (Matthijs & McNamara 2015) not only in the media but also in the national and international political discourse. For example, in German parliamentary debates over various crisis measures, only one party, the populist left "Die Linke," repeatedly deplored the fact that the bailouts were large re-distributive programs from German and peripheral taxpayers to German and other creditor states' banks (Wonka 2016). No other party discussed this issue, framing the debate on crisis management in terms of solidarity and European integration instead (Degner & Leuffen 2016, Wendler 2014). These more ideological frames seem to have resonated with the German public (Bechtel et al. 2014) and even firms (Jäger 2013). Yet many questions about creditor state politics remain unanswered. Why have left parliamentarians and trade unions in creditor states not framed the debate in terms of internal adjustment, which would justify the implementation of policies aimed at stimulating domestic demand, such as increasing the minimum wage or public spending? Why have interest groups become less visible during the crisis, and why has there been a near consensus on the crisis narrative among policy makers in Germany and Austria (Leupold 2016)? Overall, research on the domestic distributive politics of the euro crisis in creditor states is much less developed than for debtor states. Existing research mostly focuses on the political struggles over concrete policies, rather than the underlying strategic decision to give preference to a publicly funded financing strategy rather than pursuing domestic macroeconomic and structural adjustment. This is surprising, given the dominant role that creditor states have played in shaping the Eurozone's response to the crisis. Analyzing the distributive effects of the euro crisis, their interplay with ideas and narratives, and their effect on crisis politics in creditor states is thus a promising avenue for future research. CONCLUSION The Eurozone crisis has dragged on for eight years and shows no signs of ending. This is a damning indictment of the European Union's member states and of its constituent institutions. After all, one of the principal justifications for the creation of EMU was that the member states together would be able to solve problems that they could not adequately address separately. Instead, amid the most serious economic crisis in 75 years, the member states have spent nearly a decade in bitter bickering that has, if anything, exacerbated the effects of the initial financial distress. Not surprisingly, amongthe European public, trust in EU institutions (Roth etal. 2014) and democracy (Armingeon & Guthmann 2014, Cramme & Hobolt 2014) has fallen significantly over the course of the crisis, and euroskepticism is on the rise (Hobolt & de Vries 2016), with Brexit only the latest and most visible challenge to the European Union. The sources of the crisis are to be found in the political economy of European monetary integration, and in particular in the construction of a common currency with unresolved underlying conflicts over how it would be managed. These conflicts implicate powerful national interests and equally powerful particularistic special interests. The pulling and hauling of member states with conflicting interests, and of powerful groups with enormous amounts of money at stake, have driven the European Union into one of the most serious crises in its history. It will emerge from the crisis only after it manages to reconcile the various national and group interests in conflict in Frieden • Walter a manner acceptable to at least the bulk of the Union's member states and citizens. So far, it has shown little ability to find its way toward such a resolution. DISCLOSURE STATEMENT The authors are not aware of any affiliations, memberships, funding, or financial holdings that might be perceived as affecting the objectivity of this review. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This paper has benefitted from many discussions with Mark Copelovitch about the political economy of the Eurozone crisis. We thank Nils Redeker for comments and Ahmet Koken, Celine Neuenschwander, Ari Ray, and Raphael Reinke for research assistance. Stefanie Walter acknowledges funding from the Swiss National Science Foundation (Project "Distributional Conflicts and the Politics of Adjustment in the Eurozone Crisis"). LITERATURE CITED Accornero G, Ramos Pinto P. 2015. 'Mild mannered'? Protest and mobilisation in Portugal under austerity, 2010-2013. West Eur. Polit. 38:491-515 Acharya V, Drechsler I, Schnabl P. 2014. APyrrhic victory? Bank bailouts and sovereign credit risk. J. Financ. 69:2689-739 Afonso A, Zartaloudis S, Papadopoulos Y. 2015. How party linkages shape austerity politics: clientelism and fiscal adjustment in Greece and Portugal during the Eurozone crisis. J. Eur. Public Policy 22:315-34 Alt J, Lassen DD, Wehner J. 2014. It isn't just about Greece: domestic politics, transparency, and fiscal gimmickry in Europe. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 44:707-16 Ardagna S, Caselli F. 2014. The political economy of the Greek debt crisis: a tale of two bailouts. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 6:291-323 Armingeon K, Guthmann K. 2014. Democracy in crisis? The declining support for national democracy in European countries, 2007-2011. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 53:423-42 Avram S, Figari F, Leventi C, Levy H, Navicke J, et al. 2013. The distributional effects of fiscal consolidation in nine countries. Euromod Documento Trabajono 2:34-41 Baerg NR, Hallerberg M. 2016. Explaining instability in the stability and growth pact: the contribution of member state power and euroskepticism to the euro crisis. Cornp. Polit. Stud. 49:968-1009 Baldwin R, BeckT, Benassy-Quere A, Blanchard O, Corsetti G, et al. 2015. Rebooting the Eurozone: Step 1— Agreeing on a crisis narrative. CEPR Policy Insight 85:1-15 Bechtel AIM, Hainmueller J, Margalit Y. 2014. Preferences for international redistribution: the divide over the Eurozone bailouts. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 58:835-56 Bellucci P. 2014. The political consequences of blame attribution for the economic crisis in the 2013 Italian national election. J. Elect. Public Opin. Parties 24:243-63 Bellucci P, Lobo MC, Lewis-BeckMS. 2012. Economic crisis and elections: the European periphery. Electoral Stud. 31:469-71 Benetrix AS, Lane PR. 2013. Fiscal cyclicahty and EMU. J. Int. Money Financ. 34:164-76 Bentolila S, Dolado JJ, Jimeno JF. 2012. Reforming an insider-outsider labor market: the Spanish experience. IZA J. Eur. Labor Stud. 1:1. http://www.izajoels.eom/content/l/l/4 Blyth M. 2013. Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea. Oxford, UK; Oxford Univ. Press Bosco A, Verney S. 2016. Elections in Hard Times: Southern Europe 2010-11. London/New York: Routledge Broz JL, DuruM, Frieden J. 2016. Policy responses to balance-of-payments crises: the role of elections. Open Econ. Rev. 27:204-27 Bulmer S. 2014. Germany and the Eurozone crisis: between hegemony and domestic politics. West Eur. Polit. 37:1244-63 www.annttalreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis Chang M, Leblond P. 2015. All in: market expectations of Eurozone integrity in the sovereign debt crisis. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 22:626-55 Clements B, Nanou K, Verney S. 2014. 'We no longer love you, but we don't want to leave you': the Eurozone crisis and popular euroscepticism in Greece. J. Eur. Integr. 36(3):247-65 Copelovitch M, Enderlein H. 2016. Kicking the can dcrwn the road: the euro crisis and the political economy of troika bailouts. Presented at conf. Financial Crisis Management and Its Consequences in Comparative Perspective, Berlin, Apr. 7-8 Copelovitch M, Frieden J, Walter S. 2016. The political economy of the Eurozone crisis. Comp. Polit. Stud. 49(7):811-40 Cramme O, Hobolt SB. 2014. Democratic Politics in a European Union Under Stress. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press De Grauwe P, Moesen W. 2009. Common euro bonds: necessary, wise or to be avoided? Intereconomics 44:132-41 Degner H, Leuffen D. 2016. Keynes, Friedman, or Monnet? Explaining parliamentary voting behaviour on fiscal aid for euro area member states. West Eur. Polit. 39(6): 1139—59 Dinas E, Jurado I, Konstantinidis N, Walter S. 2016. Keeping the euro at any cost? Explaining preferences for euro membership in Greece. Presented at Annu. Meet. Am. Polit. Sei. Assoc., Philadelphia, PA, Sep. 1-4 Dinas E, Rori L. 2013. The 2012 Greek parliamentary elections: fear and loathing in the polls. West Eur. Polit. 36:270-82 Dyson K 2010. Norman's lament: the Greek and Euro area crisis in historical perspective. N. Polit. Econ. 15:597-608 Dyson K. 2014. States, Debt, and Power: 'Saints'* and 'Sinners^ in European History and Integration. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press Featherstone K 2015. External conditionality and the debt crisis: the 'Troika'and public administration reform in Greece. J. Eur. Public Policy 22:2')$-~!> 14 Fernandez-Albertos J, Kuo A. 2016. Economic hardship and policy preferences in the Eurozone periphery: evidence from Spain. Comp. Polit. Stud. 49:874-906 Frankel J. 2005. Contractionary currency crashes in developing countries. NBER Work. Pap. No. 11508. Natl. Bur. Econ. Res., Cambridge, MA Frankel J, Wei S-J. 2004. Managing macroeconomic crises: policy lessons. NBER Work. Pap. No. 10907. Natl. Bur. Econ. Res., Cambridge, MA Frieden J. 1991. Debt, Development, and Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press Frieden J. 1998. The euro: Who wins? Who loses? Foreign Policy 112:25-40 Frieden J. 2015a. Currency Politics: The Political Economy of Exchange Rate Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press Frieden J. 2015b. The political economy of adjustment and rebalancing. J. Int. Money Financ. 52:4-14 Genovese F, Schneider G, Wassmann P. 2016. The eurotower strikes back: crises, adjustments, and Europe's austerity protests. Comp. Polit. Stud. 49:939-67 GiugniM, GrassoM. 2016. Austerity and Protest: Popular Contention in Times of ECONOMIC CRISIS. London/ New York: Routledge Gocaj L, Meunier S. 2013. Time will tell: the EFSF, the ESM, and the euro crisis. J. Eur. Integration 35(3):239-53 Goerres A, Walter S. 2016. The political consequences of national crisis management. Micro-level evidence from German voters during the 2008/9 global economic crisis. German Polit. 25:131-53 Goulart P, Veiga FJ. 2016. Portuguese 2015 legislative elections: how economic voting, the median voter and unemployment led to 'the times they are a'changin'? Elect. Stud. 43:197-200 Gutierrez R. 2014. Welfare performance in Southern Europe: employment crisis and poverty risk. South Eur. Soc. Polit. 19:371-92 Hall PA. 2012. The economics and politics of the euro crisis. Ger. Polit. 21:355-71 Hall PA, Franzese RJ. 1998. Mixed signals: central bank independence, coordinated wage bargaining, and European Monetary Union. Int. Organ. 52:505-35 Heinen N, Kreutzmann A-K, Böttcher B, AG DB, Hoffmann R. 2015. A profile of Europe's populist parties. Ann-Kristin Kreutzmann 49:1-19 Frieden • Walter Hernandez E, Kriesi H. 2016. The electoral consequences of the financial and economic crisis in Europe. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 55:203-24 Hobolt SB, de Vries C. 2016. Turning against the union? The impact of the crisis on the Eurosceptic vote in the 2014 European Parliament elections. Elect. Stud. 44:504-14 Hobolt SB, Wratil C. 2015. Public opinion and the crisis: the dynamics of support for the euro. J. Eur. Public Policy 22:238-56 Höpner M, Lutter M. 2017. The diversity of wage regimes: why the Eurozone is too heterogeneous for the euro. Eur. Polit. Sei. Rev. In press Howarth D, Quaglia L. 2014. The steep road to European banking union: constructng the single resolution mechanism. J. Common Market Stud. 52:125-40 Howarth D, Quaglia L. 2015. The political economy of the euro area's sovereign debt crisis: introduction to the special issue of the Review of International Political Economy. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 22:457-84 IEO (Independent Evaluation Office). 2016. The IMF and the crises in Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. Washington, DC: Int. Monet. Fund. http://www.ieo-imf.org/ieo/files/completedevaluations/EAC%20-%20Full%20Report.pdf Iversen T, Soskice D, Hope D. 2016. The Eurozone and political economic institutions. Annu. Rev. Polit. Sei. 19:163-185 Jäger K. 2013. Sources of Franco-German corporate support for the euro: the effects of business network centrahty and political connections. Eur. Union Polit. 14:115-39 Johnston A, Hancke B, Pant S. 2014. Comparative institutional advantage in the European sovereign debt crisis. Comp. Polit. Stud. 47:1771-800 Jones E, Kelemen RD, Meunier S. 2015. Failing forward? The euro crisis and the incomplete nature of European integration. Comp. Polit. Stud. 49(7):1010-34 Jonung L, Drea E. 2010. It can't happen, it's a bad idea, it won't last: US economists on the EMU and the Euro, 1989-2002. Econ. J. Watch 7:4-52 Katsamdou A, Otjes S. 2016. How the European debt crisis reshaped national political space: the case of Greece. Eur. Union Polit. 17:262-84 Lane PR. 2012. The European sovereign debt crisis. J. Econ. Perspect. 26:49-67 Leupold A. 2016. A structural approach to politicisation in the Euro crisis. West Eur. Polit. 39:84-103 Mabbett D, Schelkle W. 2015. What difference does Euro membership make to stabilization? The political economy of international monetary systems revisited. Rev. Int. Polit. Econ. 22(3):508-34 Magalhäes PC. 2012. After the bailout: responsibility, policy, and valence in the Portuguese legislative election of June 2011. South Eur. Soc. Polit. 17:309-27 Marsh M, Mikhaylov S. 2012. Economic voting in a crisis: the Irish election of 2011. Elect. Stud. 31:478-84 Martin I, Urquizu-Sancho I. 2012. The 2011 general election in Spain: the collapse of the socialist party. South Eur. Soc. Polit. 17:347-63 Matsaganis M, Leventi C. 2014. The distributional impact of austerity and the recession in Southern Europe. South Eur. Soc. Polit. 19:393-412 Matthijs M, McNamara K. 2015. The euro crisis' theory effect: northern saints, southern sinners, and the demise of the eurobond. J. Eur. Integration 37:229-45 Medina I, CorreaP. 2016. The 2015 Spanish election: the times they are a'changing. Reg. Fed. Stud. 26(3):407- 17 Mundeil R. 1961. A theory of optimum currency areas. Am. Econ. Rev. 51:657-64 Niemann A, Ioannou D. 2015. European economic integration in times of crisis: a case of neofunctionalism? J. Eur. Public Policy 22{2):\96-2\% Nölke A 2016. Economic causes of the Eurozone crisis: the analytical contribution of comparative capitalism. Socio-Econ. Rev. 14:141-61 Pepinsky TB. 2009. Economic Crises and the Breakdown of Authoritarian Regimes: Indonesia and Malaysia in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press Peterson A, Wahlström M, WennerhagM. 2015. European anti-austerity protests—beyond "old" and "new" social movements? Acta Sociol. 58:293-310 Rori L. 2016. The 2015 Greek parliamentary elections: from great expectations to no expectations. West Eur. Polit. 39(6):1323-43 www. annualreviews.org • Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis Roth F, Gros D, Nowak-Lehmann DF. 2014. Crisis and citizens' trust in the European Central Bank—panel data evidence for the euro area, 1999-2012. J. Eur. Integr. 36(3):303—20 Roth F, Jonung L, Nowak-Lehmann D. 2016. Crisis and public support for the euro, 1990-2014. JCMS: J. Common Market Stud. 54(4):944-60 Schimmelfennig F. 2015. Liberal intergovernmentalism and the euro area crisis. J. Eur. Public Policy 22:177-95 Simmons B. 1994. Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy During the Interwar Years. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press Streeck W, Elsasser L. 2016. Monetary disunion: the domestic politics of Euroland. J. Eur. Public Policy 23:1-24 Walter S. 2013. Financial Crises and the Politics of Macroeconomic Adjustment. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press Walter S. 2016. Crisis politics in Europe: why austerity is easier to implement in some countries than in others. Comp. Polit. Stud. 49:841-73 Wendler F. 2014. End of consensus? The European leadership discourse of the second Merkel government during the Eurozone crisis and its contestation in debates of the Bundestag (2009-13). Ger. Polit. 23:446- 59 Wihlborg C, Willett T, Zhang N. 2010. The euro debt crisis. It isn't just fiscal. World Econ. 11:51-77 Wonka A. 2016. The party politics of the Euro crisis in the German Bundestag: frames, positions and salience. West Eur. Polit. 39:125-44 Frieden • Walter Contents Annual Review of Political Science Volume 20, 2017 Politics, Academics, and Africa Robert H. Bates ................................................................................1 Qualitative Methods ■5 John Gerring ..................................................................................15 £ a Just War Theory: Revisionists Versus Traditionalists ■s g Seth hazar ....................................................................................37 .S ° > Ö 5 * International Courts: A Theoretical Assessment § * Clifford J. Carrubba and Matthew Gabel ...................................................55 12 Political Economy of Taxation p ° Edgar Kiser and Steven M. Karceski ........................................................75 "S u Comparing Political Values in China and the West: What Can Be § 2- Learned and Why It Matters 11 Daniel A. Bell..................................................................................93 Q <2 § u Culture, Politics, and Economic Development — § P«m/ Collier..................................................................................Ill gl <1 Voter Identification Laws and Turnout in the United States % 3 Benjamin Highton........................................................................... 149 2 % Climate Change and International Relations (After Kyoto) 2'I ^4rzitf Underdal .............................................................................. 169 3 B, 1 Social Movement Theory and the Prospects for Climate Change < Activism in the United States DougMcAdam ..............................................................................189 Climate Change: US Public Opinion Patrick J. Egan and Megan Mullin........................................................209 The Political Economy of Regional Integration Christina J. Schneider.......................................................................229 Bureaucracy and Service Delivery Thomas B. Pepinsky, Jan H. Pierskalla, and Audrey Sacks...............................249 Feminist Theory Today Kathy E. Ferguson...........................................................................269 When Does Globalization Help the Poor? Nita Rudra and Jennifer Tobin ............................................................287 Measuring Public Opinion with Surveys Adam J. Berinsky............................................................................309 ^ Conflict and Cooperation on Nuclear Nonproliferation 1 Alexandre Debs and Nuno P. Monteiro....................................................331 9 .2 From a Deficit of Democracy to a Technocratic Order: The Postcrisis | 1 Debate on Europe 2 & Ignacio Sdnchez-Cuenca.....................................................................351 3 o | cK Understanding the Political Economy of the Eurozone Crisis | 2 Jeffry Frieden and Stefanie Walter ........................................................371 1 g The Electoral Consequences of Corruption o Catherine E. De Vries and Hector Solaz...................................................391 %™ -2 ^ Labor Unions, Political Representation, and Economic Inequality 11 John S. Ahlquist.............................................................................409 £ ^ Coding the Ideological Direction and Content of Policies j~ jj Joshua D. Clinton ...........................................................................433 2 § £ Wealth Inequality and Democracy ° 2* Kenneth Scheve and David Stasavage......................................................451 j | The New New Civil Wars I ^ Rwfera F. Walter ..........................................................................469 -° & § State Building in the Middle East 1 I Lisa B/aydes..................................................................................487 S Information, Uncertainty, and War Kristopher W. Ramsay ......................................................................505 Large-Scale Computerized Text Analysis in Political Science: Opportunities and Challenges John Wilkerson and Andreu Casas.........................................................529 Trading in the Twenty-First Century: Is There a Role for the World Trade Organization? Judith Goldstein .............................................................................545 Police Are Our Government: Politics, Political Science, and the Policing of Race-Class Subjugated Communities Joe Soss and Vesla Weaver............................................................... Errata An online log of corrections to Annual Review of Political Science articles may be at http://www.annualreviews .org/ errata/polisci