Democratic Transitions Author(s): David L. Epstein, Robert Bates, Jack Goldstone, Ida Kristensen and Sharyn O'Halloran Source: American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 50, No. 3 (Jul., 2006), pp. 551-569 Published by: Midwest Political Science Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3694234 Accessed: 08-09-2017 20:31 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://about.jstor.org/terms Midwest Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Political Science This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms Democratic Transitions David L. Epstein Columbia University Robert Bates Harvard University Jack Goldstone George Mason University Ida Kristensen Columbia University Sharyn O'Halloran Columbia University Przeworski et al. (2000) challenge the key hypothesis in modernization theory: political regimes do not transition to democracy as per capita incomes rise, they argue. Rather, democratic transitions occur randomly, but once there, countries with higher levels of GDP per capita remain democratic. We retest the modernization hypothesis using new data, new techniques, and a three-way rather than dichotomous classification of regimes. Contrary to Przeworski et al. (2000) we find that the modernization hypothesis stands up well. We also find that partial democracies emerge as among the most important and least understood regime types. he study of democratization is one of the most venerable literatures in comparative politics. It is also one of the most vigorous, as controversies over theory and method interact with empirical research in debates over the origins and determinants of democratic forms of government. In recent years, however, an uncharacteristic lull seems to have descended on this vibrant field-a lull we attribute to the need to absorb the pivotal contribution of Przeworski et al. (2000) (hereafter referenced PACL). Despite the challenges posed by Boix (2002) and Boix and Stokes (2003), rather than igniting debate, as would be right and proper, PACL appear instead to have quenched it. Among the most notable of PACL's findings is that modernization-specifically, an increase in per capita GDP-is not a causal factor in the process of democratization. Rather, they argue, the positive association between income and democracy results from the reduced likelihood of more modern countries sliding back, as it were, into undemocratic forms of government once having (randomly) become democratic. This finding is now treated as received wisdom. We challenge that finding. The grounds for our dissent are both methodological and substantive. PACL employ a dichotomous classification of political systems, in which governments are either democratic or authoritarian, with rather stringent requirements for being included in the former category. All countries failing to meet the necessary conditions for being a full democracy are then deemed autocratic. This approach, however, ignores the possibility of an intermediate category, "partial democracies," which possess some, but not all, of the properties that characterize full democracies. Not only are such regimes becoming more numerous, there is also growing evidence that they behave differently from either full democracies or full autocracies. Mansfield and Snyder (1995), for instance, show that partial democracies are more likely to become involved in armed conflicts with other countries. Bacher (1998) argues that countries in the similar Freedom House category of "partially free" regimes are most likely to enact policies that harm the environment. Goldstone et al. (2000) demonstrate that partial democracies are more prone to political instability, revolutions, and ethnic wars. And Zakaria (2003), terming such regimes "illiberal democracies," warns that they can be just as oppressive and contemptuous of human rights as any dictatorship. In this article, we first review and critique the work of PACL. We indicate that they mistakenly interpret their own estimates in a manner that predisposes them to reject the modernization hypothesis. Shifting from their dichotomous to our trichotomous measure of democracy, we recreate their result; employing Markov estimation, as do they, we then demonstrate that our trichotomous measure is to be preferred. Epstein, Kristensen, and O'Halloran: Department of Political Science, Columbia University; Bates: Department of Government, Harvard University; Goldstone: School of Public Policy, George Mason University. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 50, No. 3, July 2006, Pp. 551-569 02006, Midwest Political Science Association ISSN 0092-5853 551 This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 552 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN What we learn from these efforts is that higher per capita incomes increase the likelihood of a movement away from autocracy as well as decrease the likelihood of a movement away from democracy. That is, we find reason (contra PACL) to support the modernization hypothesis. In our view, democracy is a process, not an end state. And as is often the case, the journey is more important than the destination. We also learn that the frontier of this line of inquiry has shifted away from the study of autocracies and democracies and toward the study of partial democracies. As we show here, the behavior of these systems largely determines the level, rate, and properties of democratization. While thus influential, partial democracies, being highly heterogeneous, are poorly understood. The study of democratization, we therefore conclude, should place them at its focus. The following section reviews the relevant literature on modernization theory. After reviewing the results of previous research, we summarize the data used in our analysis and our statistical techniques: tobit, Markov, and duration models. We then present our own findings. The last section concludes by emphasizing the significance of partial democracies. Modernization Theory Modernization theory was first developed by Lerner (1958), a behavioral scientist studying the role of the media in development (see also Deutsch 1961). Lerner designated as modern those societies whose people are literate, urban-dwelling, and better off, in the sense of commanding higher incomes. The later works of economists, such as Rostow (1960), Kuznets (1966), and Chenery and Taylor (1968), focused on economic modernization. In so doing, they emphasized the importance of structural change and associated the rise of per capita incomes with the decline of the agrarian economy and the rise of urban industry. The classic statement of the relationship between modernization and politics originates from Lipset (1959), who first established the link between the level of per capita income and democracy in a global cross-section of nations. Lipset hypothesized that as societies develop economically, their citizens no longer tolerate repressive political regimes. The rise in per capita GDP, he argued, triggers a transition to democracy. Pioneering the small-N research tradition in comparative historical sociology, Moore (1966) related democratization to the rise of the middle class and to the terms of its political incorporation, a result upheld by Rueschemeyer, Stephens, and Stephens (1992). More common is the use of large-N data sets, with important contributions from Cutright (1963), Dahl (1971), and Burkart and LewisBeck (1994), among others. Londregan and Poole (1996) perform an especially careful test of the relation between income and democracy and find a significant, albeit modest, effect. Against this background, Przeworski and his coauthors advanced an important new argument.' Reminding us that correlation does not necessarily imply causation, PACL note that countries may become democratic due to reasons unrelated to their level of economic development. Once prosperous, however, if democracies with higher levels of GDP per capita were to avoid slipping back into autocracy, then over time the relationship between GDP and democracy would emerge. It would do so even though economic growth does not cause democratization. We agree with PACL that a true test of modernization theory should examine both the impact of GDP on democratization and its ability to promote the consolidation of established democracies. However, we take issue with their conclusion that economic development does not play a significant role in transitions away from autocracy. We dissent because we find their own work flawed and because a more refined measure of regime type generates evidence of the impact of GDP that their measure obscures. As mentioned, Boix and Stokes (2003) also challenge the PACL findings. Their criticism is somewhat muted, however, as they essentially agree with PACL that the impact of GDP on democratization in the postwar period is negligible, even though it may be statistically significant. They argue that it is the prewar period-from the late nineteenth century through the 1940s-in which the impact of GDP on democracy is most powerful. Although we agree with Boix and Stokes that the patterns of GDP and democratization are clear in the prewar period, we argue that the same patterns are important in the postwar era as well. The Work of PACL As we have observed, PACL (2000) employ a dichotomous regime classification. If (1) the chief executive is 'See Przeworski et al. (1996), Przeworski and Limongi (1997), and especially Przeworski et al. (2000). This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 553 TABLE 1 Results from PACL Table 2.12 Autoc. -+ Autoc. -- Democ. -+ Democ. Democ. Indep. Var. Autoc. (Original) (Corrected) Constant -1.144** -2.524** -2.524** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) GDP -0.201 0.329 0.329** (0.162) (0.484) (0.004) GDP2 -0.003 -0.029 -0.029 (0.874) (0.191) (0.069) GDP Growth -0.042** -0.021** -0.021* (0.003) (0.000) (0.015) N 1584 2407 2407 Pseudo R2 0.19 0.05 0.05 Note: P-values in parentheses. *denotes significance at the 0.05 level; **denotes significance at the 0.01 level. elected; (2) the legislature is elected; (3) there is more than one political party; and (4) an incumbent regime has lost power, then the country is deemed democratic; otherwise, it is classified authoritarian. Using this definition, PACL claim that increases in per capita GDP do not influence transitions from autocracy to democracy; rather, they help countries that are already democratic remain so. They base their conclusions on Tables 2.12 and 2.17 from Chapter 2 of their book. The former, reproduced as the first two columns of Table 1, performs a Markov probit regression of regime type on lagged values of per capita GDP, its square, and year-to-year GDP growth: P (Dit) = (D {Po + P1GDP + 32GDP2 + 33Growth + P41D + P3lIDGDP + 36IDGDP2 P37D Growth},(1) where P(Dit) signifies the probability that country i is a dictatorship in year t, (D(.) is the cumulative normal distribution, and ID is an indicator variable for dictatorship in the previous period.2 As indicated in the first two columns of Table 1, PACL report the coefficients on GDP and GDP2 in this regression as insignificant when predicting transitions both to and from democracy. PACL take this as evidence that the level of GDP per capita does not influence democratic transitions. Note that when ID = 1 in equation (1), the coefficient on GDP will be P1 + P5, the coefficient on GDP2 will be 32 + 36, and likewise for the constant (3o + 34) and Growth (13 + 37). PACL's Table 2.12 correctly reports these summed coefficients in the columns labeled "Transitions to democracy" (the second column of our Table 1), but the repo for 34 through P7 alone, rath coefficients. To calculate the P-values for transitions to democracy, one must perform a Wald test on the hypothesis that the sum of the appropriate coefficients is 0.3 For example, the coefficient on p1 in equation (1) is -0.201 with a P-value of 0.162, and the coefficient on P5 is -0.128 with a P-value of 0.484. The sum of the coefficients is -0.329, and PACL then correctly reverse the sign to indicate the impact of GDP on transitions from dictatorship to democracy.4 What these results tell us is that the impact of GDP on transitions to dictatorships is not significantly different from 0, and that the impact of GDP on transitions to democracy is not significantly different from its impact on transitions to dictatorship; that is, -0.329 is not significantly different from -0.201. But in this context we are interested in whether the sum of these coefficients is different from 0: that is, whether GDP is a significant predictor of transitions to democracy. And a Wald test of the hypothesis that 31 + ps = 0 shows that it can be rejected with a P-value of 0.004. Substituting the corrected P-values into the analysis yields the results reported in the last column of Table 1. As shown, these results actually run counter to PACL's central hypothesis: GDP influences transitions to democracy but not transitions to autocracy. Both the GDP and GDP2 terms, however, contribute to the total impact of GDP on transitions. To evaluate this impact, we employ the delta method, which involves evaluating the derivative P/IaGDP. For equation (1), the derivative is (o' (o + 31 GDP + ?2 GDP2 + 13 Growth) . (13 + 22GDP) (2) when ID = 0, and ' [(O + 4 (+ 1 ? + (35)GDP + + (13 + 137)Growth] [(P1 + P (3) when ID = 1. Performing these calculations, we find that the overall coefficient on GDP for transitions to autocracy is -0.0034 with a standard error of 0.0015, and for 2Relative to PACL's Table 2.12, the coefficients on GDP and GDP2 in Table 1 are multiplied by 1000. 3A Wald test is used to determine whether a linear combination of coefficient values is equal to some constant. Here we wish to test the restriction that, for instance, pi3 + P5 = 0. See Greene (2003, 484-88). All Wald tests were performed using the postestimation test command in Stata 9.0. Note that these same P-values can also be calculated by running two probits, one when the regime at time t - 1 is democratic and another when it is a dictatorship. 4The -0.329 coefficient indicates the impact of GDP on transitions from dictatorship to dictatorship, which is equal and opposite to its impact on transitions to democracy. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 554 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN TABLE 2 Results from PACL Table 2.17 Autoc. -- Democ. Autoc. -* Democ. Indep. Var. Democ. -* Autoc. (Original) (Corrected) Constant 0.114 3.414** 3.414** (0.899) (0.002) (0.000) GDP -0.547** -0.033** -0.033 (0.000) (0.000) (0.445) GDP Growth -0.022 0.018* 0.018 (0.181) (0.027) (0.079) Leadership Turnover 0.975** -0.527** -0.527** (0.001) (0.000) (0.007) Religious 0.026** -0.001* -0.001 Fractionalization (0.010) (0.014) (0.816) % Catholic 3.937* -0.369 -0.369 (0.048) (0.105) (0.707) % Protestant 2.626* 0.038 0.038 (0.039) (0.118) (0.965) % Moslem 5.087* -0.147 -0.147 (0.016) (0.932) (0.890) New Country -0.012 0.432 0.432* (0.978) (0.365) (0.039) British Colony -0.842* -0.164 -0.164 (0.048) (0.153) (0.423) Previous Transitions 0.897** -0.362** -0.362** (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) % World -3.735* -3.040 -3.040* Democracies (0.047) (0.750) (0.011) N 1584 2407 2407 Pseudo R2 0.19 0.05 0.05 Note: P-values in parentheses. *denotes transitions to democracy the coeffi a standard error of 0.0034. The tota regime change is thus significant in bo than insignificant both ways as repor PACL's Table 2.17, reproduced a columns of Table 2, reports the res Markov regression, this time witho host of other covariates. The author the coefficient on GDP is now signifi tions, but discount this result, saying of magnitude larger for democracies" indicate the basis for this statement.s As with Table 2.12, however, PACL f significance level of the sum of the r The corrected version of these results column of Table 2. This time the revise favorable to their central hypothesis: predictor of transit These results, howev highly sensitive to thus leave open the in transitions to de A Trichotomous Measure of Democratization Among the most hotly debated issues in the study of democratization is that of the choice of measures (see, for 5Indeed, this is one of the criticisms leveled at PACL by Boix and Stokes (2003). We discuss their results at further length below. 6For example, in most specifications the inclusion of the Previous Transitions variable (labeled "STRA" in PACL) makes the coefficient on GDP insignificant. But an examination of the data patterns indicates that the greater the number of previous transitions, the less of an effect GDP has on the outcome. This in turn suggests including an interactive term, and indeed when this term is added all three variables (GDP, STRA, and GDP * STRA) are significant. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 555 example, Bollen and Jackman 1999; Munck and Verkuilen 200 by defining and summarizing tion. We then describe our me ous history of democratization variables of our analysis. Identifying Partial De PACL employ a dichotomous Consider, however, the 85 au Geddes (1999, 115-16) records a the "third wave." Of these, 34 regimes, and 30 as stable democ remained contested and unstab four descended into "warlordism." Geddes's discussion thus reminds us of the significance of partial democracies, a category that dichotomous measures fail to-indeed, cannot-capture.7 Using the Polity IV scaling of regimes from -10 to +10, we categorize regimes as Autocracies (Polity value -10 to 0), Partial Democracies (+1 to +7), or (Full) Democracies (+8 to +?10).8 The Polity score is based on three components: measures of executive constraints, political competition, and the quality of political participation. In autocracies, the executive retains a high level of political discretion, often due to the absence of a strong judiciary or powerful legislature. There is no organized competition for political office. And political participation is orchestrated by those who hold power. In full democracies, the executive faces binding constraints on the use of power; there are institutionalized forms of political competition; and citizens openly propound and associations openly champion civic causes. Between these end points, there remain gradations: in partial democracies, the chief executive may be elected, but then face weak constraints; and his selection may not result from open and organized competition, but rather from lobbying by a politicized military or from selection by a committee of a ruling party. Alternatively, the election itself could be uncompetitive, either because of political manipulation by the authorities or because political parties were highly factionalized. As of 2002 (Polity scores in parentheses), Ethiopia (1), Nigeria (4), Venezuela (6), and Russia (7) illustrate what is meant by "partial democracy." While the selection of the cut points must ultimately be arbitrary, we provide three justifications. When the Polity score registers 7 or below, then the country fails to attain a maximum score on any of its three component measures. Countries with 8 or higher reach a maximum value on at least one of them; 9 or higher, on at least two; and 10 on all three. Secondly, the Polity scores yield classifications that correspond well with those employed by others. Most importantly, as noted in the discussion below, we can readily recover the classification employed by PACL using the Polity scores. Lastly, our argument is robust to changes in the cut points: we estimated the regressions reported later in the article with the cut points between adjacent categories moved one or two units in either direction, and the results did not change. In this sense, our findings are not the result of an arbitrary choice of measure. Thus defined, partial democracies comprise 14.3% of country-years in our sample, which includes 169 countries from 1960 to 2000. As Figure 1 shows, the percentage of partial democracies among the world's societies has grown markedly in recent years: it had a minimum value of 3.6% in 1976 and rose to its maximum of 26.1% in 2000, with a notable increase after the fall of the Soviet Union. The "third wave" peopled the globe with partial democracies. Whereas Figure 1 shows the overall patterns of democratization, Table 3 examines the dynamics of change from one regime category to another. It shows the distribution of autocracies, partial democracies, and democracies, conditioning on the previous year's category. The table reveals that both autocracies and full democracies are stable in the short run: an average of 97.3% of all autocracies remain autocratic the next year, while an average of 98.2% of all democracies remain democratic; thus around 2% of countries in these categories change in a given year. Partial democracies are over four times less stable, however, with 9.6% of them changing into an autocracy or full democracy the following year. These differences become even more pronounced when we expand the time horizon to five years. About 11% of all autocracies change into partial or full democracies after five years, and 7% of democracies change category five years later. The most volatile group, again by a large margin, is partial democracy: almost 40% of these change category after five years. Movements in or out of the category of partial democracy account for 80% of the transitions in our sample.9 These data highlight the importance of partial democracies: more volatile than either pure democracies 7This division is also emphasized in Collier and Levitsky (1997). 8Note that by our definition, partial democracies are truly an intermediate category, even relative to PACL's regime classification formula. In the country-years for which our data sets overlap, 97% of regimes that we code as autocratic PACL also code as autocracies, and 92% of our full democracies are democracies in their data too. But of our partial democracies, 52% are democracies and 48% are autocracies by PACL's measure. 'Appendix A provides a complete categorization of countries by their number and type of transitions. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 556 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN FIGURE 1 World Democratization Trends, 1960-2000 100", 90" L) O, h 0 0050 . , 40 m Democracy YPar 0-) Lo r- 0',. .) "1. .O.C".. . .. ..LO LC o LAI a _J Yea ZIC 31)"1o ?O 20" ! [] BIIsI ssIIss Democracyyo~vz I [] aria 10 lo, I Autocracy r r~r~~r r r r rir r-r ll 11111 l~l~i m Year TABLE 3 Regime Category Transitions-One-Year Lag Current Year Partial Previous Year Autocracy Democracy Democracy Autocracy 97.3% 2.1% 0.7% (3,121) (66) (22) Partial Democracy 6.4% 90.4% 3.3% (49) (695) (25) Democracy 1.1% 0.8% 98.2% (16) (12) (1,496) Total 3,186 773 1,543 Note: Numbers in parentheses are cell counts. or autocracies, they account for an increasing of current regimes and the lion's share of regime tions. Rather than dichotomizing countries into d racies and autocracies, then, our dependent variab be trichotomous, including a middle category for democracy. This variable is called Regime Category data set, with Autocracies coded as 0, Partial De cies as 1, and Full Democracies as 2. In creating a t category democracy measure, we heed the advice Elkins (2000), who warns that dichotomous m may obscure correlations that intermediate-grade reveal, and Collier and Adcock (1999), who sugg for studies of democratic transitions, more coarsemeasures are appropriate. Previous Democratization Many observers argue that a country's previous transition history may affect current efforts at democratization, as prior failures may spur or weaken future attempts. Goldstone and Kocornik-Mina (2005) have shown that many countries experiencing democratic transitions are "bouncers" or "cyclers" that move back and forth between autocracy and democracy on multiple occasions. We somehow need to capture prior volatility and failed efforts at achieving democracy. Despite its importance, however, a country's history of negative experience with democratization is hard to measure. Simply counting movements between categories will miss unstable behavior that consists of substantial movements toward (or away from) democracy within a single category: say from a Polity score of -10 to 0 and then back to -10. Counting the value of all changes in Polity scores, on the other hand, will treat successful and large transitions to democracy as indicating just as much volatility as a country that experiences several smaller movements toward democracy that failed and fell back. We therefore settled on a variable "Previous Transitions," which for country i in year t is the cumulative sum of the absolute values of negative changes in the Polity score for country i from 1960 up to and including year t. To illustrate the construction of this variable, Figure 2 provides the values of both the Polity score and the Previous Transitions variable for Turkey for each sample year. As the figure shows, the Polity score for Turkey varied widely over this period, from 4 up to 9, down to -2, back up to 9, back down to -5, up to 9, and then finally down to 7. Most This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 557 FIGURE 2 Illustration of Previous Transitions variable for Turkey, 1960-2000 Polity Score - PrevTrans 30 - 25 26 2 20 - 0 11 10 - 9 . C l 0 0 .5 -10 1955 1965 1975 1985 1995 2000 Year measures would show that Turkey fell out of democracy twice during the sample period, and, indeed, our measure rises at just those points where the Polity score falls. At any given time then, the variable provides an indicator of the country's prior and cumulative negative experiences with democratization.0 Other Independent Variables As independent variables, we employ the standard set of modernization indicators: log of GDP per capita, year-toyear GDP growth, the percent of the population living in cities, and log of population density." Our focus will, of course, be on per capita GDP. As controls, we use our Previous Transitions measure of prior experiences with democratization (as in Acemoglu and Robinson 2001); log of trade openness, defined as exports plus imports over GDP (as in Rodrik 1997); and a variable indicating whether over 75% of national income is derived from sales of minerals or petroleum. This latter variable captures the "resource curse" hypothesis (as in Ross 1999; Boix and Stokes 2003), which argues that countries deriving a large share of national income from easily extractable natural resources TABLE 4 Summary Statistics Std. Variable Mean Dev. Min. Max. N Polity Score -0.45 7.58 -10 10 5671 Regime Category 0.70 0.88 0 2 5671 Log of Per Capita GDP 8.14 1.04 5.64 10.21 4417 Percent Change in GDP 0.02 0.06 -0.52 1.01 4475 Percent Urban Pop. 44.94 24.29 2.3 100 5245 Log of Population 3.61 1.46 -0.49 8.77 5600 Density Log of Trade Openness 3.98 0.62 0.43 6.16 4902 Previous Transitions 3.96 6.41 0 31 5671 Resource Curse 0.23 0.42 0 1 5671 tend to be undemocratic and un descriptive statistics for all variab Statistical Method We address two distinct questi tries democratic, and what fac democracies against backsliding refers to democratization; the s We use two techniques to addr and Markov analyses-and one duration analysis. First, we shall examine demo method that takes into account t that is, our scale is limited to perhaps artificially. We employ model for these estimations, whi Polity values rather than categor Like PACL, we also use Marko However, as described above, in model (democracy and dictatorshi state model. This allows us to estimate six distinct transitions: Autocracy to Partial Democracy, Partial Democracy to Democracy, and Autocracy to Democracy, as well as the 10We note also that our Previous Transitions measure correlates with PACL's similar "STRA" variable (for sum of transitions to authoritarianism) at 90.5% for all overlapping country-years. "One might also add percent of GDP originating from agriculture to this list, but its correlation with urbanization is over 90%. Thus we use only urbanization in our analysis. 12Data Sources: Polity Score-Polity V, IRIS, University of Maryland; GDP-Penn World Tables; Urban PopulationPopulation Division of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations; Population Density-Hybrid of UN Population Division, World Development Indicators, and Banks population density series (WDI is used if UND is not available; BNK is used if WDI is not available); Trade Openness-Hybrid data series of World Development Indicators and Penn World Tables trade openness (WDI is the primary source; PWT is used if WDI is missing); Resource Curse-United Nations: Trade and Development Statistics. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 558 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN reverse of each. The Markov model treats each of these six transitions as distinct and identifies causal factors associated with each kind of change. Developed in biometrics, duration models estimate the impact of factors affecting survival. In our setting we wish to determine the factors that affect the survival of newly fledged democracies. Our analysis differs from the classic medical setting, though, in that each "patient" (or country, for us) can experience more than one episode of failure; it can fall out of democracy more than once (witness Turkey). Hence we employ a repeated-failures variant of the standard duration model.13 We wish to capture unit-specific effects, i.e., whether some countries are more "frail" (to return to a medical setting), in the sense of being (to return once again to our application) more prone to autocracy. Continuous Models with Data Censoring Tobit models account for the possibility that the data are censored at either or both ends of their range of values. That is, we assume, for country i at time t: Y~ Xit4 + Eit, Eit ~ N(0, 92), (4) Yit = Yi ifa < Yi~ b; Y = a if Yi < a; Yit = b if Yi* > b, (5) where Yi* is the implicit, or underlying value of the dependent variable, Yit is its observed value, and a and b are the upper and lower bounds of the observation interval, respectively. (For the Polity scale used in this study, a = -10 and b = +10.) This gives rise to the likelihood function: - - (Yit-Xi.))] u [((a - XitP)) a<_Ytb The first term corresponds to nonlimit observations, the second to observations at the lower limit a, and the third to observations at the upper limit b.14 The tobit methodology gives accurate estimates for processes in which data are limited to some predetermined range. It also allows for the estimation of the percent of censored observations, in order to determine the degree to which the upper and lower limits constrain the estimation. This part of the estimation, then, takes advantage of the full 21-point Polity scale. However, the technique assumes that moves up the Polity scale are caused by factors equal and opposite to those driving moves down the scale. As PACL have shown, it is often the case that a given factor may have a different impact on transitions toward, or away from, greater democracy. We therefore supplement the tobit analysis with a Markov switching model. Markov Transition Models The Markov model employs a smaller number of possible democratization categories and then estimates the probability of moving from any given state to another state in a single period. In these models, history matters: the conditions present in one period can affect the probabilities of different types of transitions in the subsequent period.'5 Markov models thus estimate equations of the form: F [Pr(Yit = bI Yt,_- = a)] = Oab + XitPa, (6) where a and b are possible regime types and F(.) is a function from the [0, 1] interval to the real line, such as the logit (F(z) = log TzZ) or probit (F(z) = )-'(z))functions. To expedite the analysis, we follow Clayton (1992) and work with cumulative transition probabilities. Assume that there are C ordered categories of the dependent variable (C = 3 for our study), labeled 0, 1,..., C - 1. It then becomes convenient to express the equations in terms of Y* variables, where Y* = 1 if Y < a. In our data, for example, if we let Yit = 0 indicate that country i is an autocracy at time t, Yit = 1 indicate partial democracy, and Yit = 2 indicate full democracy, then the translation from Y to Y* is given in Table 5. As by definition, Pr(Y < a) = Pr(Y < a - 1) + P r( Y = a), we can recover the individual transition probabilities from the set of cumulative probabilities. We therefore estimate equations of the form: F[Pr(Yit = b I Yi,_1 < a)] = Oab + Xit a, (7) for b = 0, 1, 2 and a = 0, 1, which is equivalent to equation (6), substituting values of Y* for values of Y in the previous period. One could estimate equation (7) separately for each regime type, or, as with dichotomous Markov regressions, combine the data for each value of b into a single equation, including interactions of the independent variables and lagged values of Y*: 13These models are becoming increasingly popular in political science, and our treatment of them owes much to recent work by Box-Steffensmeier and Zorn (2002). 14See Greene (2003, 764-66) for a good textbook discussion of these models. "'Variables associated with other historical aspects of a country's development, such as previous transitions to democracy, can be added to the model as independent variables. See the discussion of our Previous Transitions variable above. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 559 TABLE 5 Definition of Y* Variables Y: 0 1 2 YT: 1 0 0 YT: 1 1 0 F[Pr(Yit = b I Yi,_ = yit = b+L Yit-1 Y X f=o ==o for b = 0, 1, 2. Under this form tOab = Oab - 0(a+l)b, so a significan indicates that adjacent categories Similarly, P = 3Pc-1 and _ya = P3 y values indicate that an independ effects on transition probabilities of the lagged dependent variable. A distinctive advantage of this ap we can test whether adjacent cate variable should be collapsed. As we enables us to test the validity of o fication; to compare it to PACL's and to explore the significance of our three-way division of regim Markov model of regime type on of the adjacent categories should add a fourth type-"partial autocra between -6 and 0-the same test indicates that the full and partial autocracies should indeed be combined into a single regime category. Equation (8) can be run separately for each value of b or with an ordered probit, where the dependent variable is the ordered regime category. We begin with a "fully saturated" model, with right-hand side variables consisting of the lagged regressors (GDP, growth, urbanization, etc.), the lagged values of the indicator variables Y*, lagged Y*, and all interactions between the regressors and indicators. From this initial model, with its profusion of interactive terms, one tests down, eliminating insignificant interactions to arrive at a more parsimonious specification.16 It is the result of this procedure that we report. Survival Analysis To investigate the determinants of consolidation, we employ duration models. As mentioned above, our application differs from that in biometrics in two important ways: we think that countries might have unit-specific heterogeneity, and we know that they may experience repeated failure. In duration models, unit-specific effects are captured by "frailty" terms, written as hi(t) = Xi( t)vi, where hi(t) is the hazard rate for observation i at time t and vi is an individual-specific factor which operates multiplicatively on the hazard. In biometrics, this term captures the patient-specific susceptibility to a disease; in our setting, it refers to a country's susceptibility to autocracy. If countries differ in their frailties, but these terms are left out of the estimating equation, then there will be more variability in the actual hazard than is captured by the model (Omori and Johnson 1993). Over time, differences in frailty will cause observations to "select out" of the data; that is, low-frailty cases will stay in, while highfrailty ones will drop out. The model will then underestimate the hazard, with a corresponding overestimate of survival times. Not only is the shape of the hazard function incorrectly estimated; if the vi terms are correlated with the independent variables, then the estimated coefficients will also be biased. Analogously with panel data, these unit-specific effects can be estimated via fixed or random effects. Following Lancaster (1990), we adopt the random-effects approach, which involves choosing a specific distribution for the vi's; the most commonly used is the gamma (1, 0) distribution.'" For the estimation, we first fit a standard proportional hazards model and then choose a set of possible values for 0. For each of these values, we generate an estimated "predicted frailty" for each observation. We then fit a second duration model, this time including the estimated vi terms as an additional covariate, with a fixed coefficient of 1.0 (that is, as an offset): h(t) = ho(t)vi exp(Xi3). We then repeat these steps for each value of 0 until convergence. A second distinctive characteristic of our data is that we can have repeated failures-countries can fall out of democracy more than once-and we would not wish to impose a priori the requirement that these failures be independent of one another. In particular, methods that ignore correlations among repeated failures will tend to underestimate the standard errors. To address this property, we require that our frailty terms not be independent, but rather correlated across all 16This procedure is elaborated in Chapter 10 of Diggle, Liang, and Zeger (2002). '7See also Vaupel et al. (1979) and Manton, Stallard, and Vaupel (1981). This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 560 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN observations from a single country. The unit of observation thus becomes a "country-spell," that is, a sequential run of years in which a given country remains in a single regime. We then restrict the estimated frailty terms to be constant (in parlance, "shared") for all observations from a given country. The approach, once again, is to test down, i.e., to start with a proportional hazards model with shared frailties, and if these are not significant, then to remove this requirement and estimate a less restricted model instead. Regression Results We proceed to analyze the results from the tobit, Markov, and survival analyses described above. In each case, we estimate three models: GDP alone; GDP plus the other modernization variables; and GDP, modernization, and political control variables. The Tobit regressions also include a lagged dependent variable and control for regional effects: Africa, East Asia, Europe, Former Soviet Union, Latin America, and Near East.'8 Tobit Regressions The tobit results are given in Table 6. As indicated, GDP is significant in all specifications: countries are more likely to be democratic the higher their level of economic development. Moreover, the overall model fit is good, with a pseudo-R2 of about 40%, high enough to capture significant amounts of variation, but not so high that one would suspect that the lagged dependent variable was doing all the work. The regression results also highlight some interesting regularities. First, note that higher GDP growth rates are associated with autocracies. On its own this finding might be puzzling, but see the Markov analysis below, which indicates that this relation holds only for countries starting in autocracy. Looking at the other two modernization variables, urbanization is negatively related to democracy and population density is positively related, but neither relation is statistically significant. As for the political variables, the results on our measure of previous attempts at democratization indicate that countries that experience previous falls from democracy tend to be more democratic (but, again, see the discussion of this variable in the Markov regressions below). Trade openness is also associated with more democracy. And TABLE 6 Tobit Regression Analysis of Factors Affecting Democratic Transitions (Regional Fixed Effects Omitted) Model (1) (2) (3) Lagged Polity Score .964 .962 .962 (.006)*** (.007)*** (.007)*** GDP Per Capita .362 .385 .32 (.063)*** (.099)*** (.102)*** GDP Growth -2.458 -2.72 (.782)*** (.783)*** Pct. Urban Pop. -0.001 -.003 (.004) (.004) Population Density .059 .032 (.035)* (.036) Trade Openness .292 (.077)*** Previous .013 Transitions (.007)** Resource Curse -.067 (.113) N 4259 3789 3789 Pseudo-R2 .396 .397 .398 Note: All independent variables lagg the "resource curse" is negat but the coefficient is insigni These findings corroborate economic development to d course, subject to PACL's o variables may describe wel democracy but do not pred racy. This possibility is addre analysis below. Markov Regressi As a first look at the data, co a local regression (lowess) p and the probability of transi racy. The most obvious patte have a significant impact on both into and out of democra magnitudes. This initial view cism regarding PACL's claim from but not into democrac PACL also make much of racy has ever fallen with a $6,055, the prevailing level o it transitioned to autocracy i the probability of transition"sThe countries in each region are listed in Appendix B. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 561 FIGURE 3 Impact of GD Transition Probabiliti LC) 0 Cu I- I .OLLog of GDP Per Capita Type of Transition Into Democracy ................... Out of Democracy once a country passes this key income level. As shown in Figure 3, though, no sharp drop-off is evident; the probability of leaving democracy declines smoothly as GDP increases, without any indication that one level of wealth is more critical than another. PACL also claim that the income levels at which countries transition out of autocracy show significantly more variation than the levels at which countries transition out of democracy. Figure 4 shows that the data do not support PACL's claim: the distribution of GDP values for FIGURE 4 Distribution of GDP for Transitions To and From Democracy -9 Variance = 0.712 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 (a) Log of G (09 Variance = 0.742 C,) -2 -1 0 1 2 3 (b) Log of G This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 562 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN TABLE 7 Markov Regression Analysis Model (1) (2) (3) Lagged Yo -2.686 -2.979 -2.866 (.073)*** (.758)*** (.105)*** Lagged Yi 2.226 4.134 3.836 (.85)*** (1.491)*** (1.538)** GDP Per Capita .800 1.118 .997 (.096)*** (.202)*** (.218)*** GDP Per capita * Y1 -.622 -.971 -.803 (.105)*** (.219)*** (.231)*** GDP Growth -.127 -.385 (.973) (.986) GDP Growth * Yo -2.232 -1.844 (1.302)* (1.305) Pct. Urban Pop. -.016 -.012 (.007)** (.008) Pct. Urban Pop. * Y1 .019 .013 (.008)** (.008) Population Density .017 (.034) Population Density * Yo .075 (.049) Trade Openness .228 (.129)* Trade Openness * Y1 -.236 (.142)* Previous Transitions -.023 (.013)* Previous Transitions * Yo .033 (.009)*** Previous Transitions * Y1 .026 (.015)* Resource Curse -.185 (.098)* N 4299 3789 3789 Pseudo-R2 .773 .776 .780 Note: All independent variables lagg transitions to democracy actually variance than the distribution of income for transitions to autocracy (0.712 vs. 0.742). We begin our Markov analysis with all possible interactions between the regressors and lagged values of Y3 and YT, and then test down to a more parsimonious model. Recall that if, for example, the interaction between GDP and Y* (GDP * Y*) is significant, this means that GDP has a different effect on the level of democracy if the regime is autocratic in the previous period, as opposed to partially or fully democratic. Similarly, if GDP * Y* is significant, GDP has a different impact when the regime is fully democratic in the previous period, as opposed to the other two alternatives. Consequently, if both GDP* Y*I and GDP * Y* are significant, GDP has a different effect for all three lagged regime types. The results of this analysis are illustrated in Table 7 in raw form, showing the significance of the direct and interactive effects, and in Table 8 in a more easily interpretable format. Beginning with the former, we see that This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 563 TABLE 8 Summary of Markov Model (1) (2) (3) A 0.18*** 0.15** 0.19** GDP Per Capita P D 0.80*** 1.04*** 1.00"** A -2.34*** -2.23** GDP Growth P -0.189 -0.386 D A 0.002 -0.0001 Percent Urban Pop. P D -0.015** -0.013* A 0.095*** Population Density 0.021 D A -0.010 Trade Openness P D 0.227* A 0.035*** Previous Transitions P 0.002 D -0.024* A Resource Curse P -0.186* D Note: Coefficients refer to the relevant sums of direct and interactive effects. * = 0.10; ** = 0.05; *** = 0.01. A = Autocracy; P = Partial Democracy; D = Full Democracy. the significance levels of the coefficients on the modernization variables are similar in all three models. In particular, GDP per capita is highly significant in all specifications. Table 8 distills the results from the analysis, showing only the relevant (sums of) coefficients from the direct and interactive effects. Coefficients that straddle table rows have similar effects for the adjacent categories. In all three models, for example, GDP has a similar impact on democratization when the country in question was autocratic or partially democratic in the previous period, as opposed to fully democratic. If the country was autocratic or partially democratic, the coefficient is 0.18 (the sum of GDP and GDP * Y* in Table 7); if the country was fully democratic, then the coefficient on GDP in Model 1 is 0.80 (the direct effect from Table 7). Both are significant, as they are in Models 2 and 3 as well, indicating that higher GDP does produce more democratic regimes, no matter what the starting point, and no matter which sets of covariates are added to the estimation equation. The other findings in the table are also interesting and help shed light on the results from the Tobit analysis above. The coefficient on growth, for example, is significant only for countries starting as autocracies, in which case it inhibits democratic transitions; otherwise, growth is not a significant factor. This result explains the negative coefficient on growth in Table 6. Urbanization, on the other hand, appears to undermine democracies but has no effect on other regime categories. And population density, significant in Model 2 only, promotes transitions out of autocracy but has no impact on partially or fully democratic regimes. Turning to the political variables, trade openness helps stabilize full democracies, but it does not help autocratic or partially democratic regimes move up the ladder. The results for our Previous Transition variable illustrate the power of the Markov approach. Previous transitions destabilize autocracies, have no impact on partial democracies, and make full democracies more likely to backslide; in other words, they are a destabilizing force. Thus a single variable can have different impacts (in fact, opposite signs) depending on the starting point in the previous period. Finally, the resource curse tends to make all regime categories more autocratic. Why do our results from the Markov analysis vary so markedly from PACL's? They, after all, test a similar model to ours. Perhaps the difference comes from our coding of the dependent variable: we use Polity scores, while PACL employ their own measure of autocracy and democracy. If we substitute our Polity measure into their regressions, though, combining partial and full democracies into a single democratic category, the estimation results from PACL's model specification still hold. In particular, even with a Polity version of the dependent variable, lagged GDP is shown to be a significant predictor of transitions out of democracy, but not to democracy. Conversely, we dropped the "partial" category in our data set. With this specification, the coefficient on GDP is, as PACL concluded, significant for transitions to autocracy, but not to democracy. In both data sets, then, one can reproduce PACL's results using a dichotomous regime classification with Polity data and thus rule out the possibility that differences in the measure of democracy account for differences in our findings. Continuing in this fashion, we subdivide the two PACL regime categories into four: (1) PACL autocracies that we did not list as partial democracies; (2) PACL This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 564 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN autocracies that we list as partial democracies; (3) PACL democracies that we list as partial democracies; and (4) PACL democracies that we did not list as partial democracies. PACL combine categories one and two versus three and four, while we combine two and three together, but leave one and four as distinct categories. If our categorization is correct, then we should see relatively more transitions out of category one into categories two, three, or four than we would see from categories one and two to categories three or four. And, in fact, 2.63% of regimes transition out of category one, which is a 49% increase over the 1.76% that transition out of categories one or two. Moreover, when we run a Markov regression with GDP as an independent variable, we find that the coefficients separating categories two and three are uniformly insignificant, while those separating category one from category two and category three from category four are uniformly significant. This finding supports the use of our tripartite regime classification rather than PACL's dichotomous specification. Finally, note the elusive nature of partial democracies. Although we can gain some understanding of the factors that make autocracies (or full democracies) become partially democratic, we have little information as to the factors that would lead partial democracies to either slide down to autocracy or to move up to full democracy. In fact, examining the saturated regression with all direct and interactive effects, we find that none of the coefficients on partial democracy are significant on their own. Numerous, volatile, and shaping the dynamics of regime transitions, the determinants of the behavior of the partial democracies elude our understanding. Duration Analysis We now turn to the duration analysis, which highlights the factors that help countries stay democratic. Given our trichotomous measure of democracy, there are two ways in which we could approach this issue: what prevents full democracies from sliding back to partial democracies or autocracies, and what prevents partial democracies from sliding back to autocracy? PACL also perform duration analysis, and they argue that new democracies are in fact more likely to fail than more established ones, but that once GDP per capita is taken into account, this difference disappears. We examine this conclusion using the same three models as in the previous section. Table 9 shows the results of estimating the probabilities that states fall out of full democracy. The frailty TABLE 9 Survival Analysis of Transitions Out of Full Democracy Model (1) (2) (3) GDP Per -1.853 -2.784 -2.895 Capita (.328)*** (.65)*** (.777)*** GDP Growth -6.8 -6.526 (7.136) (7.785) Pct. Urban .041 .031 Pop. (.022)* (.026) Population .023 .02 Density (.236) (.309) Trade -1.265 Openness (.505)** Previous .067 Transitions (.04)* Resource Curse .448 (.855) N 1483 1356 1356 Log Likelihood -78.326 -63.167 -58.778 0 .383 .67 .895 Note: All independent var ***=.01. terms were significant in all specifications, and so they are retained in the estimation equations. Note first that in all specifications, higher GDP per capita reduces the probability that countries fall out of democracy. Other than this finding, however, the results offer few clues as to the factors that help prevent backsliding. Higher urban populations are a risk factor for democracies in Model 2, and trade openness is a stabilizing factor in Model 3, but no other coefficients are significant. Figure 5 graphs the impact of GDP on transitions, plotting the smoothed hazard rates both with and without adjustment for GDP per capita.19 The top figure shows that the risk of falling out of democracy rises at first, then declines after the first seven years as a full democracy. The bottom figure tells a very different story. Here, after adjusting for GDP per capita, the risk of failure rises steadily for about 20 years, and then plateaus. To put it another way, it is the average increase in per capita GDP that causes the reduction in the hazard rate in the top figure. The key to consolidation of new democracies, it would appear, is a strong economy. '19The adjustment sets GDP per capita at its mean value and calculates hazard rates for all other variables. The fact that the curve flattens out is evidence that variation in GDP accounts for the Ushaped function in the top figure. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 565 FIGURE 5 Adjusted and of Democracy Smoothed Hazard Estimate for Leaving Democracy Unadjusted a: U, 0 I 0 10'o 20 30Years Adjusted for GDP per Capita cc 0-- o 10 2'0 30 Years Note: Gaussian Kernel Smoothing We now repeat the above analysis for partial democracies, to see if similar factors keep semidemocratic societies from falling back into autocracy.20 Here, the frailty terms were never significant and were dropped from the estimation. Table 10 presents the results. Compared with transitions from full democracy, the predictive ability of these models is much smaller. The coefficient on GDP per capita is again negative in all specifications, but marginally significant in Model 2 and insignificant in Model 3. The only other significant variables are trade openness and the resource curse in Model 3, the former associated with less risk of falling into autocracy, the latter with increased risk.21 And the log likelihoods of all models are smaller than those in Table 9. Neither does Figure 6 offer much evidence as to the factors that affect the consolidation of partial democracies. The unadjusted hazard rate in the top half of the figure rises gently, turning negative only after 13 years (at which point there are relatively few data points remaining in the sample). This general pattern does not change, even after adjusting not just for GDP, but for all independent variables in Model 3. As in the Markov analysis, then, the factors affecting transitions out of partial democracy remain poorly understood. TABLE 10 Survival Analysis of Transitions from Partial Democracy to Autocracy Model (1) (2) (3) 20Since we are interested in the question of stabilizi racies, transitions to full democracy are treated a vations in this part of the analysis. 21One might also reasonably inquire whether cou partial democracies after falling out of full dem ferent patterns in their hazard rates. To evaluate a variable FullToPart was added to the analysis, significant. GDP Per -.695 -.692 -.603 Capita (.221)*** (.356)* (.395) GDP Growth 3.939 4.295 (3.651) (3.799) Pct. Urban -.002 -.006 Pop. (.014) (.017) Population .008 .034 Density (.131) (.166) Trade -.882 Openness (.351)** Previous -.006 Transitions (.026) Resource Curse .903 (.513)* Obs. 703 627 627 e(ll) -153.779 -131.85 -128.113 Note: All independent variables lagged o ***=.01. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 566 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN FIGURE 6 Adjusted and Unadjusted Hazard Rates for Transitions from Partial Democracy to Autocracy Smoothed Hazard Estimate for Leaving Partial Democracy Unadjusted o LO 0 5 10 15 20 Years Adjusted for All Independent Variables M ?L 0 5 10 15 20 Years Note: Gaussian Kernel Smoothing Conclusion This article has returned to the analysis of the relationship between modernization and democracy. In doing so, it has reappraised the central argument of the works of PACL, the standard against which all other work in this field should be measured. We find that PACL themselves erred in their own analysis, failing to correctly estimate the standard errors of the coefficients reported in their Markov model, and that when doing so, they erred in a way that led them to report the impact of GDP on democratization as insignificant. As did PACL, we too employed Markov methods; when we did so, we found reason to prefer a three-category classification of democratic regimes to the dichotomous categorization that they employed. Classifying countries into autocracies, democracies, and partial democracies, we demonstrated that higher incomes per capita significantly increased the likelihood of democratic regimes, both by enhancing the consolidation of existing democracies and by promoting transitions from authoritarian to democratic systems. Our trichotomous measure proved valuable for an additional reason: it highlighted the significance of the middle category--the partial democracies-a category whose properties and significance were necessarily obscured in the PACL analysis. These are "fragile" democracies, or perhaps "unconsolidated democracies." Whatever one wishes to call them, they emerge from our analysis as critical to the understanding of democratic transitions. More volatile than either straight autocracies or democracies, their movements seem at the moment to be largely unpredictable. One of our major conclusions, then, is that it is this category--the partial democracies-upon which future research should focus. We also note that this is one area of scholarly inquiry with important implications for policy. In the present era, countries are reforming both politically and economically. Politically, they seek democracy. Economically, they pursue policies to promote economic growth. Should these reforms be sequential or simultaneous, and if sequential, which-the political or the economic-should come first? PACL's (2000) conclusion that economic growth does not aid democratization, while democratic political institutions foster growth, puts them squarely in the "politics first" camp. In arguing with PACL's conclusions, though, we do not mean to imply that economic reforms should take This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 567 primacy over the political, as the p the issues of reciprocal causality in Indeed, the current literature on po exactly these causality issues by try instrument for institutions, broadl in turn affected by the level of eco Rodrik, Subramanian, and Trebbi use the widely known Acemoglu, J (2001) measure of settler mortality tutional quality. They find that ins important as determinants of econ either geography or trade. Glaese Silanes, and Shleifer (2004) disagree claiming that in fact better property ships help spur economic growth, w the emergence of democratic gover To this fruitful, ongoing debate w that leaving autocracy is not the sa racy. Between these two lie parti often act in a manner distinct from more or less democratic than the ics, while shaping contemporary po understood. Appendix A: Descriptive Statistics on Transitions We have 169 countries in the data set.22 Their patterns of stability and transitions are as follows: * 41 very stable countries: same Polity value throughout the data set - 23 very stable full democracies with Polity value of 1023 - One very stable democracy with Polity value of 824 - Four very stable partial democracies existing between eight and 11 years25 - 13 very stable autocracies26 * 42 stable countries: same category (autocracy, partial, or democracy) throughout the data set but Polity value changes - Four stable democracies27 - Four stable partial democracies28 (Note: none of these countries is more than 10 years old.) - 34 stable autocracies29 After identifying the very stable and the stable countries, we want to characterize the countries making transitions between categories. Two features seem to be of interest: how many categories the country visited during our time period and the direction of the changes. Concerning the latter feature, we distinguish between somewhat stable countries making a single transition during the time period studies and unstable countries making several transitions. * 56 shifting between two categories - Nine shifting between partial and democracy * Four somewhat stable: three countries up to democracy30 and one down to partial31 * Four unstable countries going up once and down once32 - 37 shifting between partial and autocracy * 22 somewhat stable: 15 up to partial33 and seven down to autocracy34 * 17 unstable35 22Twenty-five countries that existed during our sample period had no Polity scores: Andorra, Antigua & Barbuda, Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brunei, Cape Verde, Dominica, Grenada, Liechtenstein, Maldive Islands, Malta, Monaco, Palau, San Marino, Sao Tome-Principe, Seychelles, Solomon Islands, St. Kitts-Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, Vanuatu, and Western Samoa. 23Countries existing in all 41 years are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Costa Rica, Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, and United Kingdom. Countries existing less than all 41 years are Czech Republic (8), Germany (11), West Germany (30), Lithuania (10), Papua New Guinea (26), and Slovenia (10). 24Latvia (10). 25Estonia (10), Ethiopia after 1993 (8), Macedonia (10), Namibia (11). 26Countries existing in all 41 years are Bhutan, Cuba, Libya, and Saudi Arabia. Countries existing less than all 46 years are Eritrea (8), East Germany (29), Kyrgyzstan (10), Qatar (30), United Arab Emirates (30), Uzbekistan (10), Vietnam (25), South Vietnam (16), and Yemen (11). 27 Israel, Jamaica, Mauritius, and Trinidad. 28 Georgia, Moldova, Russia, and Ukraine. 29Afghanistan, Algeria, Angola, Bahrain, Burundi, Cameroon, Chad, China, Congo-Kinshasa, Egypt, Gabon, East Germany, Guinea, Iraq, Jordan, Kazakhstan, North Korea, Kuwait, Laos, Liberia, Mauritania, Morocco, Oman, Rwanda, Swaziland, Syria, Tajikistan, Togo, Tunisia, Turkmenistan, USSR, North Vietnam, North Yemen, South Yemen, and Former Yugoslavia. 30Botswana, France, Slovakia, and South Africa. 31Malaysia. 32Columbia, France, India, and Sri Lanka. 33Central African Republic, C6te d'Ivoire, Croatia, Djibouti, El Salvador, Guinea-Bissau, Honduras, Indonesia, Iran, Malawi, Mali, Mozambique, Paraguay, Tanzania, and Yugoslavia. 34Belarus, Equatorial Guinea, Kenya, Singapore, Somalia, Syria, and Zimbabwe. 35Up once and down once: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Benin, Burkina Faso, Guyana, Pakistan (pre-1972), and Zambia. More shifts: Albania, Cambodia, Comoros, Congo-Brazzaville, Ghana, Haiti, Nepal, Sierra Leone, and Uganda. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms 568 DAVID L. EPSTEIN, ROBERT BATES, JACK GOLDSTONE, IDA KRISTENSEN, AND SHARYN O'HALLORAN - 11 shifting between autocracy and democracy * Nine somewhat stable: seven countries up to democracy36 and two down to autocracy37 * Two unstable countries going two categories up once and two down once38 30 shifting between all three categories - Only in one direction * Six countries up39 and none the other way - 24 back and forth * 12 countries making three transitions between categories40 * Four making four transitions41 * Four making five transitions42 * Two making six transitions43 * One making seven transitions44 Appendix B: Countries in Each Region Africa: Angola, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo-Brazzaville, Congo-Kinshasa, C6te d'Ivoire, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Eritrea, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Somalia, South Africa, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zambia, Zimbabwe East Asia: Australia, Burma, China, Fiji, Indonesia, Japan, North Korea, South Korea, Laos, Malaysia, Mongolia, New Zealand, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Singapore, Solomon Islands, Taiwan, Thailand, Vietnam Europe: Albania, Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Macedonia, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, Yugoslavia Former Soviet Union: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Estonia, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldova, Russia, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Ukraine, USSR(Soviet Union), Uzbekistan Latin America: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Trinidad, Uruguay, Venezuela Near East: Afghanistan, Algeria, Bahrain, Bangladesh, Bhutan, Egypt, India, Iran, Iraq, Israel, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Morocco, Nepal, Oman, Pakistan, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Sri Lanka, Syria, Tunisia, United Arab Emirates, Yemen 36Bolivia, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Portugal, Senegal, and Spain. 37Burma and Laos. 38Lesotho and Uruguay. 39Mexico, Mongolia, Nicaragua, Poland, Romania, and Taiwan. 40Bangladesh, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Fiji, Gambia, Greece, Madagascar, Niger, Panama, Philippines, and Venezuela. 41Dominican Republic, Guatemala, Pakistan (post-1972), and Sudan. 42Argentina, Ecuador, Nigeria, and South Korea. 43Peru and Turkey. 44Thailand. References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson. 2001. "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation." American Economic Review 91:1369-1401. Acemoglu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2001. "A Theory of Political Transitions." American Economic Review 91:938- 63. Bacher, John. 1998. "Oil and Dictatorship." Peace Magazine 14:8. Boix, Carles. 2002. Democracy and Redistribution. New York: Cambridge University Press. Boix, Carles, and Susan Stokes. 2003. "Endogenous Democratization." World Politics 55:517-49. Bollen, K., and Robert Jackman. 1989. "Democracy, Stability, and Dichotomies." American Sociological Review 54:612-21. Box-Steffensmeier, Jan, and Christopher Zorn. 2002. "Duration Models for Repeated Events." Journal ofPolitics 64:1069-94. Burkhart, Ross E., and Michael S. Lewis-Beck. 1994. "The Economic Development Thesis." American Political Science Review 88:903-10. Chenery, Hollis B., and Lance J. Taylor. 1968. "Development Patterns: Among Countries and Over Time." Review of Economics and Statistics 50:391-416. Clayton, David G. 1992. "Repeated Ordinal Measurements: A Generalised Estimating Equation Approach." Medical Research Council Biostatistics Unit Technical Report. Cambridge, England. Collier, David, and Robert Adcock. 1999. "Democracy and Dichotomies: A Pragmatic Approach to Choices about Concepts. Annual Review of Political Science." In Annual Review of Political Science, ed. Nelson Polsby. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms DEMOCRATIC TRANSITIONS 569 Collier, David, and Steven Levitsky. 1 jectives: Conceptual Innovation in C World Politics 49:430-51. Cutright, Phillips. 1963. "National Political Development: Social and Economic Correlates." In Politics and Social Life: An Introduction to Political Behavior, ed. Nelson W. Polsby, Robert A. Dentler, and Paul A. Smith. Boston: Houghton Mifflin, pp. Dahl, Robert A. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press. Deutsch, Karl W. 1961. "Social Mobilization and Political Development." American Political Science Review 55(3):493-510. Diggle, Peter, Kung-Yee Liang, and Scott Zeger. 2002. Analysis of Longitudinal Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Elkins, Zachary. 2000. "Gradations of Democracy? Empirical Tests of Alternative Conceptualizations." American Journal of Political Science 44(2): 293-300. Goldstone, Jack, et al. 2000. State Failure Task Force: Phase III Findings. McLean, VA: SAIC. Goldstone, Jack A., and Adriana Kocornik-Mina. 2005. "Democracy and Development: New Insights from Dynagraphs." George Mason University, Center for Global Policy, Working Paper #1. Fairfax, VA. Geddes, Barbara. 1999. "What Do We Know About Democratization After Twenty Years?" Annual Review ofPolitical Science 2:115-44. Glaeser, Edward, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2004. "Do Institutions Cause Growth?" Journal of Economic Growth 9:271-303. Greene, William. 2003. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall. Jaggers, Keith, and Ted R. Gurr. 1995. "Tracing Democracy's Third Wave with the Polity III Data." Journal ofPeace Research 31(4):469-82. Kuznets, Simon. 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure, and Spread. New Haven: Yale University Press. Lancaster, Tony. 1990. The Econometric Analysis of Transition Data. New York: Cambridge University Press. Lerner, Daniel. 1958. The Passing of Traditional Society. New York: Free Press of Glencoe. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1959. "Some Social Requisites of Democracy." American Political Science Review 53:69-105. Londregan, John B., and Keith T. Poole. 1996. "Does High Income Promote Democracy?" World Politics 49:1-30. Mansfield, Edward, and Jack Snyder. 1995. "Democratization and War." Foreign Affairs 74:79-97. Manton, Kenneth G., Eric Stallard, and James W. Vaupel. 1981. "Methods for Comparing the Mortality Experience of Heterogeneous Populations." Demography 18(August):389- 410. Moore, Barrington. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Boston: Beacon Press. Munck, Gerardo L., and Jay Verkuilen. 2002. "Conceptualizing and Measuring Democracy: Evaluating Alternative Indices." Comparative Political Studies 35:5-34. Omori, Yasuhiro, and Richard A. Johnson. 1993. "The Influence of Random Effects on the Unconditional Hazard Rate and Survival Functions." Biometrika 80(4):910-14. Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 1996. "What Makes Democracies Endure?" Journal of Democracy 7:3-36. Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development. New York: Cambridge University Press. Przeworski, Adam, and Fernando Limongi. 1997. "Modernization: Theories and Facts." World Politics 49:155-83. Rodrik, Dani. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington: Institute for International Economics. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004. "Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development." Journal of Economic Growth 9:131-65. Ross, Michael L. 1999. "The Political Economy of the Resouce Curse." World Politics 51:325-61. Rostow, Walt Whitman. 1960. The Stages of Economic Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens. 1992. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Vaupel, James W., Kenneth G. Manton, and Eric Stallard. 1979. "The Impact of Heterogeneity in Individual Frailty on the Dynamics of Mortality." Demography 16:439-54. Zakaria, Fareed. 2003. The Future ofFreedom. New York: W. W. Norton. This content downloaded from 147.251.55.4 on Fri, 08 Sep 2017 20:31:04 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms