1 94 Energy during the interwar years Colombian Petroleum. 1920-1940," Canadian Journal of History, 9 (August 1974), pp. 179-96; Rippy. "US and Colombian Oil," pp. 19-35; Chester, US Oil Policy, pp. 144-7; Wilkins. Multinational Enterprise, pp. 255-72. 56. J. Foreman-Peck, .-1 History of the World Economy: lnernational Economic Relations since 1850. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books (1983), p. 213; for a concise analysis of the worst years of the depression, see P. Fearon, The Origins and Nature of the Great Slump, 1929-1932, Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press (1979). 57. For the above three paragraphs: S. Takahashi, Japan and World Resources, Tokyo: Kenkyusha Press (1937) and Royal Institute of International Affairs. Information Department, Raw Materials and Colonies. New York: Oxford University Press (1936) summarize the conflicting positions of the Axis powers and their antagonists. See also, Schumpeter, Industrialization of Japan, pp. 43-4, 373-5, passim; Takahashi, Japan, p. 29; C.C. Concannon et al., World Chemical Developments in 1935. US Department of Commerce. Bureau of Foreign and Domestic Commerce. Trade Information Bulletin No. 832, Washington, DC: GPO (1936), pp. 19, 23, 29, 36; tvl. Erselcuk, "Japan's Oil Resources," Economic Geography, 22 (January 1946), p. 16; Anderson, Standard-Vacuum, pp. 80-7; Chester, US Oil Policy, pp. 297-301; World Petroleum, 13 (January 1942), pp. 23-7. 4_ Energy flows in a politically polarized world World War II strongly influenced the energy future of the world. To the victor come the spoils. Had the war commencing in 1939 been concluded on terms favorable to the Axis powers, one might imagine them in possession of the Soviet Union's Baku fields, much of the Middle East, and the Netherlands East Indies. What an impact such an outcome would have had on the Allied powers and on the giant firms that dominated the world oil industry. Far more was at risk than oil or other natural resources, but one can still conjecture that the economies and societies of Britain, the USA, and other nations would have evolved quite differently had the Axis dictated terms of access to Middle East oil. Energy and World War II Each of the major belligerents committed substantial resources to securing a fuel supply sufficient for the prosecution of a highly mobilized conflict fought on distant and shifting fronts. Germany and Japan, without domestic oil reserves and the latter without adequate coal, planned campaigns to conquer fuel-producing regions while investing heavily during the 1930s in the development of synthetic fuel technologies. In both nations the production of coal, the chief feed stock for synthetics, cnjo\cd high pnonK. Neither Britain nor the United States made provisions belore 1939 for an emergency fuel supply. The UK felt reasonably secure. British companies controlled the largest oil fields in the Middle East and operated successHilK in sate regions in the western hemisphere. A more than adequate domestic coal supply was available. For its part, the USA 95 96 Energy in a politically polarized world Energy and World War II 97 possessed large and accessible petroleum and coal reserves and dominated the oil industries of South America and Saudi Arabia, the latter's potential still unrecognized. The USSR, with enormous productive potential in all fuels, experienced the destruction or seizure of much of its western based coal industry and its Baku oil fields. With great effort and the provision of several lend lease refineries by the USA, the Soviet Union produced and refined about 60 percent of its petroleum needs.1 The belligerents grossly miscalculated their energy requirements. Germany and Japan possessed stocks and access to supplies sufficient only for a relatively short war. Germany's conquests in Europe added the sizable coal production of Poland and France, some part necessarily devoted to sustaining the conquered populations, the oil fields of Romania, and the Maikop fields of the northern Caucasus, the latter so thoroughly destroyed by retreating Soviets that they added nothing to the oil stock of the Third Reich. Neither did the other conquests yield more than marginal increments to fuel supplies. By 1943, heavy and sustained Allied air attacks pulverized Germany's fuel industry, particularly the synthetics complex, and its transportation links. Oil became desperately short by 1944. Shortages of aviation gasoline severely hampered the operation of the Luftwaffe during the last year of the war. As labor productivity declined, partially due to malnutrition among miners, coal production in occupied France and Belgium fell off severely by 1943. Maintenance and transportation services also became increasingly inadequate. Forced labor in German mines maintained the labor force at adequate levels, but dreadful working conditions resulted in low productivity. Falling supplies of coal in 1943 and 1944 hamstrung the production of iron and steel and synthetic fuels. Japan launched its war against the USA and other European states with a natural resource base more limited than that of Germany. The need for oil determined that Japan would strike south to seize the Netherlands East Indies. Japan's hopes rested on the fatally optimistic assumption that the USA would not persist in a long and costly struggle. With a much less developed synthetic fuel industry than Germany, Japan depended upon ocean transport for the bulk of its oil and some of its coal. American control of the sea lanes by late 1944 placed virtually each Japanese oil tanker at risk. By early 1945, Japan's oil stocks had dwindled lo under one million barrels. An almost total blockade of the home islands by US naval and air forces denied Japan access to the oii of Southeast Asia. Shortages of oil and coal severely constrained war industries. Perhaps even more deadly in 1945 was the looming specter of widespread starvation.: British complacency in 1939 about fuel supplies gave way to despair by 1940. As German piano pounded the UK. submarines sunk an increasing tonnage of tankers. The intercession of the USA in 1940 through the exchange of American destroyers for bases in British possessions, the Lend Lease Act of March 1941, and the transfer of fifty oil tankers to Britain in May 1941 relieved the situation. Petroleum stocks climbed well above the danger zone. Although Nazi submarines destroyed an enormous tonnage of tankers after America's entry into the war, supplies from America were not jeopardized. The destruction of Axis armies in North Africa in 1942 eliminated the threat to the Suez and the Persian Gulf oil fields. Thereafter, American production supplemented by Venezuelan and Middle Eastern oil provided more than adequate fuel to Allied forces. Military demands for fuel compelled the heavy intervention of the British and American governments in their energy industries. In the USA, a complex of federal agencies successfully maintained adequate production of fuels, particularly aviation gasoline and chemical feedstocks for synthetic rubber, distributed fuels to the Allies and to domestic wartime industries without totally denying supplies to non-critical industries or the civilian sector, and moderated inflationary pressures. But these agencies and the policies they implemented were swiftly abandoned in 1945 and 1946. America preferred, as in 1918, to return to an essentially unregulated regimen for petroleum and coal.3 A prewar heritage in the UK of intermittent government intervention in the coal industry and in the energy utilities combined with severe wartime conditions to propel Britain toward national ownership. Beginning in 1939 all energy was strictly rationed, far more so than in the USA. By 1943, the Ministry of Fuel and Power controlled coal prices and miners' wages, an intervention necessitated by inflationary pressures, labor scarcity, and other operational problems. The government operated the mines while the mine owners retained financial responsibility. The Labour Party called for the immediate nationalization of coal. While the Conservative Party resisted this demand, it supported continuing state authority to compel industry rationalization. Labour's electoral victory after the war led immediately to the nationalization of coal and the electric and gas utilities.4 While petroleum remained in private hands in both Britain and the USA. the foreign policies of both nations presumed continued access to cheap oil. thus assuring a competitive/cooperative Anglo-American relationship concerning foreign fields. Britain's dependency upon foreign oil was total but the national energy mix during and immediately after the war still reflected the dominance of coal which, in 1950. provided 90 percent of total primar\ energs requirements.^ America's consumption of oil was far greater, with all but a fraction supplied domesticalh. In both nation1-, knowledgeable ! ? 8- C O. •2 y a o 5 E S? TO ^■5 ll •s ,? 5 "a ■Si , TO TO y « &■ 0 s - tu 1 E ^ ts C3 " I"! i- 0O < on ^5 . 3 to on « E so Jo a I "a r-' g; O o E c 2 c = a. ^ < >. $31.8 billion with petroleum's portion climbing from 15 to 34 percent and reaching $10.8 billion in 1960. Then, from 1955 to 1970, the industry invested some $215 billion in the search for and marketing of oil. The share devoted to production in the USA fell off sharply in response to more lucrative opportunities elsewhere. The investments of individual MNOCs cannot be tabulated but reference to capital expenditures hints at their magnitude. From 1950 to 1966, SONJ's capital expenditures totaled $13.9 billion out of a net income of $21.8 billion. Standard's income-expenditure ratio averaged 0.63 over that period, reflecting its self-financing capability and its low long-term debt, a characteristic of other giant oil companies as well. In 1960, the firms listed in Table 4.7 provided 30 percent of a total global oil investment of $10.8 billion.39 Suffocation by numbers? Perhaps! But such figures, at the least, capture the essence of aggregate and individual Big Eight dominance. Few observers, excepting oil industry officials and inveterate advocates of giant enterprise, perceived such control of the industry as a natural consequence of economies of scale and as a boon to consumers.40 Adelman, Al-Otaiba, Leeman, Luciani, Odell, Penrose, among others, each specified the political and institutional forces that permitted the evolution of such concentrations of power in the oil industry.41 Historically, the early concessions in Latin America and the Middle East resulted from the application of overwhelming US and European economic and political pressure on the weak governments in those areas. Ruling cliques in Turkey and Persia (and then Iraq and Iran), Saudi Arabia, Venezuela, and Mexico, entranced by visions of immense royalties and other payments, turned the national patrimony over to foreigners on terms wholly favorable to the MNOCs. Furthermore, western governments deliberately fostered the emergence of such giant firms as AIOC and RDS. In the USA, anti-trust legislation and occasional anti-trust indictments failed to retard industrial concentration at home or abroad. Rarely were American MNOCs inconvenienced by anti-trust proceedings. In an oblique way, then, the US government fostered the evolution of the highly concentrated structure of the post World War II oil industry. Into the 1950s. Big Eight concessions in the Persian Gulf encompassed the entire producing area with the onlv significant deviation