Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War Stephen Van Evera International Security, Volume 22, Number 4, Spring 1998, pp. 5-43 (Article) Published by The MIT Press For additional information about this article [ Access provided at 20 Sep 2020 19:38 GMT from Carleton University Library ] https://muse.jhu.edu/article/446910/summary the Causesof War 1 Is war more likely when conquest is easy? Could peace be strengthened by making conquest more difficult? What are the causes of offense dominance?' How can these causes be controlled?These are the questions this article addresses. I argue that war is far more likely when conquest is easy, and that shifts in the offense-defense balance have a large effect on the risk of war. Ten warcausingeffects (summarizedin Figure 1)arise when the offense dominates.(1) Empires are easier to conquer. This invites opportunistic expansion even by temperate powers (explanation A). (2) Self-defense is more difficult; hence states are less secure. This drives them to pursue defensive expansion (explanation B). (3)Their greater insecurity also drives states to resist others' expansion more fiercely. Power gains by others raise larger threats to national security; hence expansionism prompts a more violent response (explanation C). (4)First-strike advantages are larger, raising dangers of preemptive war (explanation D). (5) Windows of opportunity and vulnerability are larger, raising dangers of preventive war (explanationE). (6)Statesmore often adopt fait accompli diplomatic tactics, and such tactics more often trigger war (explanation F). (7)Statesnegotiateless readily and cooperatively;hence negotiations fail more often, and disputes fester unresolved (explanationG). (8)States enshroud foreign and defense policy in tighter secrecy, raising the risk of Stephen Van Evera teaches international relations in the Political Science Department at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Thanks to Robert Art, Charles Glaser, and an anonymous reviewer for their comments on this article. It is distilled from Causesof War,VolumeI: The Structure of Power and the Roots of War (Ithaca, N.Y.:Cornell UniversityPress, forthcoming1999). 1. In this article"offense dominant" means that conquestis fairly easy; "defense dominant" means that conquestis very difficult.It is almostnever easierto conquer than to defend, so I use "offense dominant"broadly, to denotethat offense is easierthan usual,although perhapsnot actuallyeasier than defense.I use "offense-defense balance" to denote the relativeeaseof aggressionand defense against aggression. As noted below, this balance is shaped by both military and diplomatic/ political factors.Twomeasuresof the overalloffense-defense balance work wek (1) the probability that a determinedaggressorcould conquerand subjugatea target statewith comparableresources; or (2) the resource advantage that an aggressor requires to gain a given chance of conquering a target state. I use "offense" to refer to strategic offensive action-the taking and holding of territory-as opposed to tactical offensive action, which involves the attack but not the seizure and holding of territory. International Security, Vol. 22, No. 4 (Spring1998),pp. 5-43 0 1998 by the President and Fellowsof HarvardCollege and the Massachusetts Instituteof Technology. 5 International Security 22:4 I 6 miscalculation and diplomatic blunder (explanation HI. (9) Arms racing is faster and harder to control, raising the risk of preventive wars and wars of false optimism (explanation I). (10) Offense dominance is self-feeding. As conquest grows easier, states adopt policies (e.g., more offensive military doctrines) that make conquest still easier. This magnifies effects 1-9 (explanation J). The perception of offense dominance raises these same ten dangers, even without the reality. If states think the offense is strong, they will act as if it were. Thus offense-defense theory has two parallel variants, real and perceptual. These variants are considered together here. How does this theory perform in tests? Three single case-study tests are performed below. They corroborate offense-defense thee$ and indicate that it has large theoretical importance: that is, shifts in the offense-defense balance-real or perceived-have a large effect on the risk of war. The actual offense-defensebalance has marked effects; the effectsof the perceived offensedefense balance are even larger. What causes offense and defense dominance? Military technology and doctrine, geography, national social structure, and diplomatic arrangements (specifically, defensive alliances and balancing behavior by offshore powers) all matter. The net offense-defense balance is an aggregate of these military, geographic, social, and diplomatic factors. How can offensedominance be controlled?Defensivemilitary doctrines and defensive alliance-making offer good solutions, although there is some tension between them: offensive forces can be needed to defend allies. Offense dominance is more often imagined than real, however. Thus the more urgent question is: How can illusions of offense dominance be controlled? Answers are elusive because the roots of these illusions are obscure. On balance, how does offense-defensetheory measure up? It has the attributes of good theory. In addition to having theoretical importance, offensedefense theory has wide explanatory range and prescriptive richness. It explains an array of important war causes (opportunistic expansionism, defensive expansionism,fierce resistance to others' expansion,first-strike advantage, 2. I use "offensedefensetheory" to label the hypothesisthat war is more likely when conquest is easy, plus explanatory hypotheses that define how this causation operates. The classic work on the topic is Robert Jervis,"Cooperationunder the SecurityDilemma," World Politics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (January1978),pp. 167-214 at 169. An overview is Sean M. Lynn-Jones,"Offense-DefenseTheory and Its Critics,"Security Sfudies, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Summer1995),pp. 660-491.The theory I frame here subsumesand elaborates on Jervis's theory. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 7 windows of opportunityand vulnerability,faits accomplis, negotiation failure, secrecy, arms races, and offense dominance itself) that were once thought to be independent.In so doing, offense-defensetheory explains the dangers that these war causesproduce and the wars they cause.This simplifiesthe problem of power and war: a number of disparate dangers are fed by a single taproot. Moreover, both the reality and the perception of easy conquest can be shaped by human action;hence offense-defensetheory offers prescriptionsfor controlling the dangers it frames. The next section outlines offense-defensetheory’s ten explanations for war. The following sectionidentifiescauses of offense and defense dominance. The fourth section frames predictions that can be inferred from offense-defense theory, and offers three case studies as tests of the theory: Europe since 1789, ancient China during the Springand Autumn and WarringStatesperiods, and the United States since 1789. The final section assesses the general quality of offense-defensetheory. Hypotheses on the Effects of Offense Dominance A host of dangers arise when conquest is easy. Some are obvious and some more subtle, some are direct and some indirect.Together they make war very likely when the offense dominates. A: OPPORTUNISTIC EXPANSIONISM When conquest is hard, states are dissuaded from aggression by the fear that victory will prove costly or unattainable. When conquest is easy, aggressionis more alluring: it costs less to attempt and succeeds more often? Aggressors can also move with less fear of reprisal because they win their wars more decisively,leaving their victims lessable to retaliate later. Thus even aggressor states are deterred from attacking if the defense is strong, and even quite benign powers are tempted to attack if the offense is strong. B AND C: DEFENSIVE EXPANSIONISM AND FIERCE RESISTANCE TO EXPANSION When conquest is hard, states are blessed with secure borders; hence they are less aggressiveand more willing to accept the status quo. They have less need 3. Suggesting this hypothesisareIvanS. Bloch, TheFuture of War,trans. R.C.Long, pref.W.T. Stead (New York Doubleday and McClure, 1899), pp. xxx-mi, lxxix; also George H. wester, Offense and Defense in the International System (New York JohnWdey and Sons, 19m,p. 9. Acorroborating test is JohnJ. Mearsheimer, Conventional Deterrence (Ithaca, N.Y.:Cornell University Press, 1983). lnternational Security 22:4 1 8 for wider borders because their current frontiers are already defensible.They have less urge to intervene in other states’ internal affairs because hostile governments can do them less harm. Conversely when conquest is easy, states are more expansionist because their current borders are less defen~ible.~They covet others’geographic strong points, strategic depth, and sourcesof critical raw materials. They worry more when hostile regimes arise nearby because such neighborsare harder to defend against. These motives drive states to become aggressors and foreign interven o r ~ . ~States also resist others’ expansion more fiercely when conquest is easy. Adversaries can parlay smaller gains into larger conquests; hence stronger steps to prevent gains by others are more appropriate. This attitude makes disputes more intractable. The basic problem is that resources are more cumulative when conquest is easy.The abilityto conquer others and to defend oneself is more elasticto one’s control over strategic areas and resources. As a result, gains are more additive-states can parlay small conquests into larger ones-and losses are less reversible. Hence small losses can spell one’s demise, and small gains can open the way to hegemonic dominance. States therefore compete harder to control any assets that confer power, seeking wider spheres for themselves while fiercely resisting others’ efforts to expand. This problem is compounded by its malignant effect on states’ expectations about one another’s conduct. When conquest is hard, states are blessed with neighbors made benign by their own security and by the high cost of attacking others. Hence states have less reason to expect attack. This leaves states even more secure and better able to pursue pacific policies. Conversely, when the offense dominates, states are cursed with neighbors made aggressive by both temptation and fear. These neighbors see easy gains from aggression and danger in standing pat. Plagued with such aggressiveneighbors, all states face 4. As Robert Jervisnotes, ”when the offense has the advantage over the defense, attacking is the best route to protecting what you have...and it will be hard for any state to maintain its size and influence without trying to increase them.” Jervis, ”Cooperation under the Security Dilemma,” p. 211; see also pp. 168-169, 173, 187-199. 5. It also seems possible that states should be more careful to avoid war when conquest is easy, because war then brings greater risk of total defeat. If so, offense dominance should cause more cautionthan belligerenceamong states,and should lower the risk of war. Advancingthis argument isJamesFearon, “TheOffense-Defense Balanceand War since1648,”paper prepared for the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Chicago, February 1995, pp. 18-24. Fearon’s argument seems deductively sound, but history offers very few examples of policymakers who argued that offense dominance was a reason for caution. This is one of many cases where deduction and the historical record point in opposite directions. Ofense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 9 greater risk of attack. This drives them to compete still harder to control resources and create conditions that provide security. Thus states become aggressors because their neighbors are aggressors. This can proceed reciprocally until no state accepts the status quo. D: MOVING FIRST IS MORE REWARDING When conquest is easy, the incentiveto strikefirst is larger because a successful surprise attack provides larger rewards and averts greater dangers. Smaller shifts in ratios of forces between states create greater shifts in their relative capacity to conquer and defend territory. (Areversal in the force ratio between two states from 2 to 1to 1to 2 means little if attackers need a 3 to 1advantage to conquer; it means everything if an attacker needs only a 1.5to 1advantage.) Hence a surprise strike that shifts the force ratio in the attacker‘s favor pays it a greater reward. This expands the danger of preemptive war and makes crises more explosive. States grow more trigger-happy, launching first strikes to exploit the advantage of the initiative, and to deny it to an opponent: Conversely, if the defense dominates, the first-move dividend is small because little can be done with any material advantage gained by moving first. Most aggressors can be checked even if they gain the initiative, and defenders can succeed even if they lose the initiative. Hence preemptive war has less attraction. E: WINDOWS ARE LARGER AND MORE DANGEROUS When conquest is easy, arguments for preventive war carry more eight.^ Smaller shifts in force ratios have larger effects on relative capacity to conquer or defend territory; hence smaller prospective shifts in force ratios cause greater hope and alarm. Also, stemming decline by using forceis more feasible because rising states can be overrun with greater ease.This bolsters arguments for shutting ”windows of vulnerability” by war. As a result, all international change is more dangerous. Events that tip the balance of resources in any direction trigger thoughts of war among states that face relative decline. Conversely, if the defense dominates, arguments for preventive war lose forcebecause declining states can more successfullydefend against aggressors even after their decline, making preventive war unnecessary. States are also 6. The classicdiscussionof these dangersis ThomasC. shelling, Amzs and Influence (New Haven, Corn.: Yale University Press, 1966), pp. 221-259. 7. For a discussionof the dangers of preventive war, see JackS. Levy, “DecliningPower and the PreventiveMotivation for War,” World Politics, Vol. 40,No.1 (October 19871, pp. 82-107. International Security 22:4 I 10 deterred from preventive war by the likelihood that their attack will fail, defeated by their enemy's strong defenses. F: FAITS ACCOMPLIS ARE MORE COMMON AND MORE DANGEROUS When conquest is easy, states adopt more dangerous diplomatic tactics-specifically, fait accompli tactics-and these tactics are more likely to cause war. A fait accompli is a halfway step to war. It promises greater chance of political victory than quiet consultation, but it also raises greater risk of violence? The acting side moves without warning, facing others with an accomplished fact. It cannot retreat without losing face, a dilemma that it exploits to compel the others to concede. But if the others stand firm, a collision is hard to avoid. Faits accomplis also pose a second danger: because they are planned in secret, the planning circle is small, raising the risk that flawed policies will escape scrutiny because critics cannot quarrel with mistaken premises. Faits accomplis are more common when the offense dominates because the rewards they promise are more valuable. When security is scarce, winning disputes grows more important than avoiding war. Leaders care more how spoils are divided than about avoiding violence, because failure to gain their share can spell their doom. This leads to gain-maximizing, war-risking diplomatic strategies-above all, to fait accompli tactics. Faits accomplis are more dangerous when the offense dominates because a successfulfait accompli has a greater effect on the distribution of international power. A sudden resource gain now gives an opponent more capacity to threaten its neighbors' safety. Hence faits accomplis are more alarming and evoke a stronger response from others. States faced with a fait accompli will shoot more quickly because their interests are more badly damaged by it. G: STATES NEGOTIATE LESS AND REACH FEWER AGREEMENTS When conquest is easy, states have less faith in agreements because others break them more often; states bargain harder and concede more grudgingly, causing more deadlocks; compliance with agreements is harder to venfy; and 8. On fait accompli strategies, see Alexander L. George, "Strategiesfor Crisis Management," in Alexander L. George, Avoiding War:Problems of Crisis Management (Boulder,Colo.: Westview, 19911, pp.377-394 at 382383, alsopp. 549-550,553-554. Other discussionsof faits accomplisinclude R.B. Mowat, DipZornacy and Peace (London:Williams and Norgate, 19351, chap. 10 (on "suddendiplomacy");Richard Ned Lebow, Between Peace and War: The Nature of International Crisis (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 19811, pp. 57-97 (on "brinkmanship"); and Thomas C. Schelling, Strategy of Conflict (New York Oxford University Press, 19631, pp. 22-28 (on games of "chicken"). Offense, Defense, and the Causes of war I zz states insist on better verification and compliance.As a result, statesnegotiate less often and settle fewer disputes; hence more issues remain unsettled and misperceptions survive that dialogue might dispel. States break agreements more quickly when the offense dominates because cheating pays larger rewards. Bad faith and betrayal become the norm. The secure can afford the luxury of dealing in good faith, but the insecure must worry more about short-term survival. This drives them toward back-alley behavior, including deceits and sudden betrayalsof all kinds-diplomatic faits accomplis, military surpriseattacks,and breaking of other solemn agreements. Hence compliance with agreements is less expected. When states do negotiate, they bargain harder and concede less when the offense dominates. Agreements must be more finely balanced to gain both sides’ agreement, because a relative gain by either side poses greater risks to the other’s safety. Verification of compliancewith agreementsis both more necessaryand more difficult when the offense dominates. States insist on better verification of the other’s compliance because smaller violations can have larger security implications;for example, an opponent might convert a small advantagegained by cheating on an arms control agreement into a larger offensive threat. At the same time, verification of compliance is harder because states are more secretive when securityis scarce (seeexplanationG). As a result, the range of issues that can be negotiated is narrowed to the few where near-certain verification is possible despite tight state secrecy. As a net result, states let more disputes fester when the offense dominates. H: STATES ARE MORE SECRETIVE Governmentscloak their foreign and defense policies in greater secrecywhen conquest is easy. An information advantage confers more rewards, and a disadvantage raises more dangers: lost secrets could risk a state’s existence. Thus states compete for information advantage by concealing their foreign policy strategies and military plans and forces. Secrecy in turn is a hydra-headed cause of war. It can lead opponents to underestimate one another‘s capabilities and blunder into a war of false optimism? It can ease surprise attack by concealingpreparationsfrom the victim. It opens windows of opportunity and vulnerability by delaying states’ reac- 9. On wars of false optimism, see Geoffrey Blainey, The Causes of War, 3d ed. (NewYork Free Press, 19881, pp. 35-56. Figure1.Offense-DefenseTheory Primehypothesis:Warismorelikelywhenconquestiseasy. ExplanationA OffenseIExphationB dominanceIExplanationC and/or perceptionof offense dominance ExplanationD ExplanationE: ExplanationF ExplanationG: ExplanationH ExplanationI: ExplanationJ: *lntP=Interveningphenomenon. HypothesisA1 HypothesisB1 HypothesisCi >opportunisticexpansion(IntP*A) >Defensiveexpansion(IntPB) >Fierceresistancetoexpansion >Movingfirstismorerewarding(In*D) byotherstates(IntPC) HypothesisDi - >Windowsarelarger,and moredangerous(In*E) moredangerous(Id'F) feweragreements(IntPG) HypothesisEl HypothesisFI >Faitsaccomplisaremore HypothesisGI >Statesnegotiatelessandreach - HypothesisHi >Secrecyismorecommonand moredangerous(IntPHI Moreintensearmsracing(IntPI) >Offensegrowsevenstronger(IntPJ) Hypothesis11 HypothesisJ1 > x Q 0 5. Olcfense,Defense, and the Causes of War I 13 tions to others' military buildups, raising the risk of preventive war. It fosters policy blundersby narrowing the circleof expertsconsulted on policy, increasing the risk that flawed policies will survive unexamined. It prevents arms control agreementsby making compliance harder to verify. I: STATES ARMS RACE HARDER AND FASTER Offense dominanceintensifies arms racing, whereas defense dominanceslows it down." Arms racing in turn raises other dangers. It opens windows of opportunity and vulnerability as one side or the other races into the lead. It also fosters false optimism by causing rapid military change that confuses policymakers' estimatesof relative power. Thus offensedominanceis a remote cause of the dangers that arms racing produces. Stateshave sevenincentivesto build largerforceswhen the offenseis strong. .Resources are more cumulative (see explanations B and C). Wartime gains and losses matter more: gains provide a greater increase in security, and losses are less reversible. Therefore the forces that provide these gains and protect against these losses are also worth more. 0 Self-defenseis more difficultbecause others' forces have more inherentoffensivecapability.Hence statesrequiremore forcesto offsetothers' deployments. 0 States are more expectant of war. Their neighbors are more aggressive (see explanation B), so they must be better prepared for attack or invasion. 0 The early phase of war is more decisive. Lacking time to mobilize their economiesand societiesin the event of war, states maintain larger standing forces." Thepossibility of quick victoryputs a premium on forces-in-being." 0 States transfer military resources from defense to offense because offense is more effective (see explanation J). Others then counterbuild because their neighbors' capabilitiesare more dangerous and so require a larger response. States also infer aggressive intent from their neighbors' offensive buildups, leading them to fear attack and to build up in anticipation. 0 States hold military secrets more tightly when the offense dominates (see explanation H). This causes rational overarming, as states gauge their defense efforts to worst-case estimates of enemy strength, on grounds that 10. See Jervis,"Cooperationunder the Security Dilemma," pp. 172,188-190. 11. See ibid., pp. 172, 189. 12. GeneralJosephJoffrearguedfor a larger French standingforce in 1913,because"theaffair will already have been settled"by the time reservistswere mobilized in three to four weeks. David G. Hemnann, The Arming of Europe and the Making of fheFirst World War (Princeton, N.J.:Princeton UniversityPress, 1996),p. 193. International Security 22:4 I 14 underspending is disastrous whereas overspending is merely wasteful. It also allows national militaries to monopolize defense information more tightly. Given that militaries are prone to inflate threats, states will overspend groundlesslywhen militaries have an informationmonopoly that lets them alone assess the threat. Thus "action-reaction" becomes "action-over- reaction-overreaction." 0 States reach fewer arms control agreements when the offense dominates, because agreements of all kinds are fewer (seeexplanationG). Hence states are less able to limit arms competition through agreement. If the defense dominates, things are reversed. Statesbuild smaller offensive forces because offense is less effective, and because other states have less aggressive aims. States are safe without wider empires; hence offensiveforces that could provide empires lose utility. The national military therefore grows defense-heavy.This causesother states to feel safer, which in turn makes them less aggressive, further lowering all states' insecurity-hence their need for empire and for offenseup to a point. States also reduce defensive forces when the defense dominates because defense is easier and attack seems more remote. Moreover, as their neighbors buy less offense, they need even less defense because their defense faces less challenge. In short, states buy smaller forces in general, and less offense in particular, when the defense dominates. This leads to still smaller forces and still less offense. If information were perfect, arms racing would slow to a crawl if the defense strongly dominated. J. CONQUEST GROWS STILL EASIER Offensedominanceis self-reinf~rcing'~for three main reasons. First, statesbuy relatively more offensive forces when the offense dominates. They prefer the more successfultype of force, so they buy defensiveforces when the defense is strong and offensive forces when the offense is strong.14This reinforces the initial dominanceof the defense or the offense. 13. Making this argumentis Jervis,"Cooperationunder the Security Dilemma,"pp. 188,199,201. 14. Thus Clausewitz explained"If attack were the strongerform [of war], therewould be no case for using the defensive, since its purpose is only passive.No one would want to do anything but attack.Defense would be pointless."Carl von Clausewitz,On War,ed. and trans.MichaelHoward and Peter Paret, intro. by Paret, Howard, and Bernard Brodie, commentaryby Brodie (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 19761, p. 359. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 15 Second, alliances assume a more offensive ~haracter'~when the offense dominates because aggressorscan more easily drag their allies into their wars of aggression.16Insecure states can less afford to see allies destroyed, so they must support even bellicose allieswho bring war on themselves.Knowing this, the allies feel freer to get into wars. As a net result, even de jure defensive alliances operate as defensive-and-offensivealliances. Alliances also assume a more offensivecharacter if the allies adopt purely offensivemilitarydoctrines. This hamstrings states that would demand that their allies confine themselves to defensive preparations in a crisis, given that all preparations are offensive. Third, status quo states are less able to protect their allies from conquest when the offense dominates because attackers can overrun defenders before help can arrive. Thus offense dominance raises the danger of greater offense dominance. Once entered, an offense-dominant world is hard to escape. Military offense dominance has one self-limiting effect: it leads status quo powers to cooperate more closely against aggressor^.'^ They jump to aid an aggressor's victims because each knows that its neighbor's demise could lead more directly to its own undoing. Conversely, when states think that the defense dominates, they do less to save others from aggression because each expects it can defend itself alone even if others are overrun. As a result, aggressorscan more often attack their victims seriatim, which is far easier than defeating a unified coalition.This countervailingeffect, however, is more than offset by the several ways that offense dominance feeds itself. These are the dangers raised by offense dominance. As noted above, these same ten dangers arise when the offense is weak but governments think it dominates. They then act as if it dominates, with comparable effects. Are offensive capabilities always dangerous? The one-sided possession of offensive capabilities by status quo powers that face aggressors can lower rather than raise the risk of war under some conditions.Most important, status quo powers often need offensive capabilities to defend other states against 15. A defensive alliance is conditioned on defensive behavior by the ally; the alliance operates if the ally is attacked but not if it attacks. A defensive-and-offensivealliance operates in the event of war regardless of which side started it. The distinction began with Thucydides, who used "empimachy" to denote defensive alliance, "symmachy" for defensive-and-offensive alliances. G.E.M.de Ste. Croix, The Origins of the Peloponnesian War (Ithaca, N.Y.:Cornell University Press, 16. Developing this point are Thomas J. Christensen and JackSnyder, "ChainGangs and Passed Bucks: Predicting Alliance Patterns in Multipolarity," International Organization, Vol. 44, No. 2 (Spring 1990), pp. 137-168. 17. Making this argument is ibid. 1972),pp. 60,72-73,106-108, 184,298-302,328. International Security 22:4 I 16 aggressors (e.g., as France required some offensive capability to defend Czechoslovakiaand Poland from Germany in 1938-39). Offensive capabilities in the hands of status quo powers also may provide more deterrence than provocation if the aggressor state knows that it provoked the status quo power’s hostility, if the aggressor knows that the status quo power has no bedrock aggressive intentions, and if the aggressor cannot remove the status quo power’s offensive threat by force. These conditions are not unknown but they are rare. Hence offensive capabilities usually create more dangers than they dampen. Causes of Offense and Defense Dominance The feasibility of conquest is shaped by military factors, geographic factors, domestic socialand political factors, and the nature of diplomacy. Discussions of the offense-defensebalance often focus on military technology,but technology is only one part of the picture.” MILITARY FACTORS Military technology,doctrine,and force posture and deploymentsall affect the military offense-defensebalance.” Militarytechnology can favor the aggressor or the defender. In past centuries, strong fortification techniquesbolstered the defense, and strong methods of siege warfare strengthened the offense. Technologies that favored mass infantry warfare (e.g., cheap iron, allowing mass production of infantry weapons)strengthened the offense because large mass armies could bypass fortifications more easily, and because mass armies fostered more egalitarianpolitiesthat could raise loyal popular armiesthat would not melt away when sent on imperial expeditions.Technologies that favored chariot or cavalry warfare (e.g., the stirrup) strengthenedthe defense,because cavalry warfare required smaller forces2’ that were more easily stopped by 18. For a discussion of the causes of offense and defense dominance, see Jervis, ”Cooperation under the Security Dilemma,’’ pp. 176,1941199. 19. Several measures of the military offense-defensebalance could be adopted, such as: (1)the probability that an offensiveforcecan overcome a defensive force of equal cost; (2) the relative cost that attackersand defendersmust pay for forces that offset incremental improvementsby the other; or (3)the loss ratio when an offensiveforceattacks a defensiveforce of equal cost. All three measures (and more are possible) capture the concept of relative military difficulty of conquest and defense. For a list of possible measures, see Charles L. Glaser and Chaim Kaufmann, “What Is OffemDefense Balance and How Can We Measure It?,” Internafional Security, Vol. 22, No. 4 (Spring 19981, pp. 44-82. 20. Cavalry warfare was capital intensive; hence it was usually waged by small forces of taxsupported specialists-knights in shining (and expensive) armor on expensive horses. M a n q warfare is more manpower intensive, and is usually waged by larger, less capihbzed armies. Ofiense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 17 fortifications,and fostered hierarchic societiesthat could not raise armies that would remain loyalif sent on questsfor empire?’ In modem times, technology that gave defenders more lethal firepower (e.g., the machine gun) or greater mobility (e.g.,the railroad)strengthened the defense.When these technologies were neutralized by still newer technologies (motorized armor), the offense grew stronger. Thus when fortresses and cavalry dominated in the late Middle Ages, the defense held the advantage. Cannons then made fortificationsvulnerable and restored the strength of the offense. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries new fortification techniques strengthened the defense. The mercenary armies of the age also remained tightly tied to logistical tails that kept them close to home: one historian writes that an eighteenth-centuryarmy “was like a diver in the sea, its movements strictlylimited and tied by the long, slender communicating tube which gave it life.”” Then revolutionary France’s mass armies strengthenedthe offense because they had greater mobility. Their size let them sweep past border forts without leaving the bulk of their manpower behind for siege duty, and their more loyal troops could be trusted to forage without deserting, so they needed less logistical support. After the conservative restoration in France, Europe abandoned the mass army because it required, and fostered, popular government. This restored the power of the defense,which then waned somewhat as Europe democratizedand large mass armies reappeared in the mid-nineteenth century?3 The combined effects of lethal small arms (accurate fast-firing rifles and machine guns),barbed wire, entrenchments,and railroads gave the defensean enormous advantage during World War I. The first three-lethal small arms, barbed wire, and trenches-gave defenders a large advantage at any point of attack. The fourth-railroads-let defenders reinforce points of attack faster than invaders could, because invaders could not use the defenders’ railroads (given that railroad gauges differed across states,and defendersdestroyed rail lines as they retreated) while the defenders had full use of their own lines. During 191945 the power of the offense was restored by motorizedarmorand an offensive doctrine-blitzkrieg-for its employment; this overrode machine 21. On the effects of the stimtp on warfare and society in the Middle Ages, see Lynn White, Jr., Medimuf Technologyand Social Change (New York:Oxford University Press, 19641,pp. 1-38.On the general effect of military technology on social stratification,see Stanislav Andreski, Military Orgunimtion and Society (Berkeley:University of California Press, 19711,pp. 20-74. 22.Harold Temperley,quoted in Blainey, Causes of War, p. 188. 23. Large armies aid the offense only up to a point, however.Once armies grow so big that they can cover an entire frontier (as on the western front in World War I), their size aids the defense because offensive outflankingmaneuvers against them become impossible. Znternational Security 22:4 1 28 guns, trenches, and barbed wire. Then after 1945 thermonuclear weapons restored the power of the defenscthis time giving it an overwhelming ad- vantage.24 Technology and doctrine combined to define these tides of offense and defense. Sometimes technology overrode doctrine, as in 1914-18 and in 1945- 91 (when the superpowers’ militaries embraced offensive doctrines but could not find offensive counters to the nuclear revolution). Sometimes doctrine shaped technology as in 193945, when blitzkrieg doctrine fashioned armor technology into an offensive instrument. States shape the military offense-defense balance by their military posture and force deployments. Thus Stalin eased attack for both himself and Hitler during 1939-41 by moving most of the Red Army out of strong defensive positions on the Stalin Line and forward into newly seized territories in Poland, Bessarabia, Finland, and the Balticstates.25This left Soviet forcesbetter positioned to attackGermany and far easier for Germany to attack, as the early successof Hitler’s 1941 invasion revealed.The U.S. eased offense for both itself and Japan in 1941 when it deployed its fleet forward to Pearl Harbor and bombers forward to the Philippines?6Egypt eased Israel’s assault by its chaotic forward deployment of troops into poorly prepared Sinaipositionsin the crisis before the 1967 war.27 States also can change the offense-defense balance through their wartime military operations. Aggressive operations can corrode key enemy defenses, and reckless operations can expose one’s own defenses. Thus the dangers of offense dominance can be conjured up by unthinking wartime policymakers. For example, General Douglas MacArthur’s reckless rush to the Yalu River in 1950 created an offensive threat to China’s core territory and, by exposing badly deployed U.S. forces to attack, eased a Chinese offensiveF8 24. Jack Levy provides synoptic history of the military offense-defense balance in ”The Offensive/Defensive Balance of Military Technology: A Theoretical and Historical Analysis,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 28, No. 2 (June 19841,pp.219-238 at 23C-234. Otherdiscussionsinclude Quester, Offense and Defense in the International System; and Andreski, Military Orgunktion and Society, pp. 75-78. A detailed history is needed. 25. Peter Calvocoressi and Guy Wmt, Total War: The Story of World War II (New York Pantheon Books, 19721, p. 168. 26. JonathanG.Utley, Going to Warwith Japan,1937-1941 (Knoxville:Universityof TennesseePress, 19851, pp. 84, 163. 27. Donald Neff, Warriorsfor lerusalem:The Six Days That Changed the Middle East (NewYork Simon and Schuster, 1984), pp. 141, 168. 28. Likewise, during the Cold War some worried that NATO might inadvertently threaten the Soviet Union’s strategic nuclear deterrent in its effort to defend NATO’s Atlantic sea-lanes during Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 19 GEOGRAPHY Conquestis harder when geography insulates states from invasion or strangulation. Hence conquest is hindered when national borders coincide with oceans, lakes, mountains,wide rivers, dense jungles, trackless deserts,or other natural barriers that impede offensive movement or give defenders natural strong points. Human-made obstacles along borders, such as urban sprawl, can also serve as barriers to armored invasion. Conquestis hindered if foes are separated by wide buffer regions (third states or demilitarized zones) that neither side can enter in peacetime. Conquest is hindered when national territories are mountainous or heavily forested, and when populations live mainly in rural settings, easing guerrilla resistance to invaders. Conquest is hindered when states are large and their criticalwar resources or industries lie far in their interior, where they cannot be quickly overrun. Conquest is hindered when statesare invulnerableto economicstrangulation.Hence conquest is hindered when states are self-sufficientin supplies of water, energy, food, and critical raw materials, or when their trade routes cannot be severed by land or sea blockade. The geography of Western Europe, with its mountain ranges and ocean moats, is less favorableto conquestthan the exposed plains of Eastern Europe or the open terrain of the Middle East. Israel’s geography is especially unfortunate: physically small, its frontiers have few obstacles and much of its industry and population lie on exposed frontiers. Israeli territory is not conduciveto guerrillaresistance,and its economyis import dependent.Germany’s borders are better but still relatively poor: its eastern frontier is open; its economy is import dependent; and its trade routes are vulnerable. Britain, France, and Italy have formidable frontier barriers that make them relatively defensible.The United States’vast size, ocean-moatfrontiers,and independent economy bless it with very defensible geography. SOCIAL AND POLITICAL ORDER Popular regimes are generally better at both conquest and self-defense than are unpopular regimes, but these effects do not cancel out. On net, conquest is probably harder among popular than unpopular regimes today, but in past centuries the reverse was likely true. an East-Westconventionalwar. Bany R. Posen,Inadvertent Escalation: Conventional War and Nuclear Risks (Ithaca, N.Y.:Cornell University Press, 1991), pp. 129-158. O n a related danger, see ibid., pp. 28-67. International Security 22:4 I 20 Popular governments can better raise larger, more loyal armies that can bypass others' border forts and can operate far from home with less logistical support. This gives popular regimes greater offensivepower. Popular regimes can better organize their citizens for guerrilla resistance, making them harder to conquer. Citizen-defense guerrilla strategies are viable for Switzerland or China, but not for Guatemala or ancient Sparta, because these unpopular governments cannot arm their people without risking revolution. The citizens of unpopular oligarchies may actively assist advancing invaders. This gives attackers more penetrating power and makes early losses less reversible. Thus Sparta feared an invading army might grow if it entered Spartan territory, because Spartan slaves and dissident tribes would desert to the enemy.29 Unpopular regimesare more vulnerableto subversionor revolutioninspired from abroad. Subversion is a form of offense, and it affects international relations in the same way as do offensive military capabilities. Frail regimes are more frightened of unfriendly neighbors, making them more determined to impose congenialregimes on neighboring states. The French revolutionary regime and the oligarchic Austrian regime worried that the other side might subvert them in 1792, causing both sides to become more aggre~sive.~'After the Russian Revolution similar fears fueled Soviet-Western conflict, as each side feared subversion by the other. On balance, is conquest easier in a world of popular or unpopular regimes? Popularity of regimes probably aided offense before roughly 1800 and has aided defense since then. The reversal stems from the appearance of cheap, mass-produced weapons useful for guerrilla war-assault rifles and machine guns, light mortars, and mines. The weapons of early times (swordand shield, pike and harquebus, heavy slow-firingmuskets, etc.)were poorly adapted for guerrilla resistance.Guerrillawarfare has burgeoned since 1800partly because the mass production of cheap small arms has tipped the balance toward guerrillas, allowing the hit-and-run harassment that characterizes guerrilla operations.The defensive power of popular regimeshas risen in stepwith this increase in guerrilla warfare. 29. De Ste. Croix,Origins of the Peloponnesian War,pp. 89-94. Likewise, Hannibalhoped to defeat Rome by recruiting dissident tribes as he penetrated the Italian peninsula.See RM.Errington, Dawn of Empire: Rome's Rise to World Pmer (Ithaca, N.Y.:CornellUniversityh),pp. 62-64. 30. StephenM. Walt, Revolution and War(Ithaca,N.Y.:Cornell Universitym,I%), pp. 123-124; and T.C.W. Blanning,TheOriginsof theFrenchReuolutionay Wars(London:Longman,19849,pp. 76, 8586,9!9-101,111. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I22 DIPLOMATIC FACTORS Three types of diplomatic arrangements strengthen the defense: collective securitysystems,defensivealliances,and balancingbehaviorby neutral states. All three impede conquest by adding allies to the defending side. States in a collective security system (e.g., the League of Nations) promise mutual aid against aggression by any system member. Such aggressors will face large defendingcoalitions if the system operates3' Statesin a defensive alliancepromisemutual aid against outsideaggressors, leaving such aggressors outnumbered by resisting opponents. Thus during 1879-87 Bismarck wove a network of defensive alliances that discouraged aggression and helped preserve peace throughout central and eastern Europe. Collective securitysystemsand defensive alliancesdiffer only in the kind of aggressor they target (systemmembersversus outsideaggressors).Both kinds of aggressors could be targeted at once, and a hybrid system that did this would offer defenders the most protection. Neutral states act as balancers when they join the weaker of two competing coalitions to restore balance between them. Aggression is self-limiting when neutralsbalance because aggressorsgeneratemore opposition as they expand. Britain and the United States traditionallyplayed balancers to Europe, providing a counterweight to potential continentalhegemons. Balancing behavior is more selective than defensive alliance. Balancers balance to avert regional hegemony; hence pure balancers opposeexpansiononly by potential regional hegemons. Smaller states are left free to aggress. But balancing does contain hegemons and leaves their potential victims more secure.Conversely,if statesbandwagon-join the strongercoalitionagainst the weaker one-conquest is easier because aggressors win more allies as they seize more Diplomatic arrangements have had a large influence on the offense-defense balance in modern Europe, and shifts in diplomatic arrangementshave pro- 31. An introductionto collective securityis lnisL. Claude, Jr., Swords into Plowshares: TheProblems and Progress ofIntemafional Organizations, 4th ed. (New York Random House, 1971),pp. 411433. Arecent advocacyof collective securityis CharlesA. Kupchanand Clifford A. Kupchan,"Concerts, CollectiveSecurity, and the Future of Europe," International Security, Vol. 16, No. 1(Summer1991), 32. On balancing,bandwagoning,and other theories of alliances, see StephenM. Walt, The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987).Historians have often suggested that a "breakdown in the balance of power/' caused war. They usually mean (and should recast their claim to say) that states failed to engage in balancing behavior, which made aggression easier, causing war. War occurs not when the balance of power breaks down, but when balancers fail to balance, leaving aggressorsunchecked, as in the late 1930s. pp. 114-163. International Security 22:4 I 22 duced large shifts in the overall offense-defense balance. Collective security was never effective, but defensive alliances came and went, erecting barriers to conquestwhen they appeared.Balancingbehaviorrose and fell as the power and activism of the two traditional offshore balancers, Britain and the United States, waxed and waned. When the United Statesand/or Britain were strong and willing to intervene against aspiring continental hegemons, conquest on the continent was difficult. To succeed, a hegemon had to defeat both its continental victims and the offshore power. But when Britain and the United Stateswere weak or isolationist, continentalpowers could expand against less resistance, leaving all states less secure. Tests of Offense-Defense The0y What predictions can be inferred from offense-defense theory? How much history does offense-defensetheory explain? PREDICTIONS AND TESTS Offense-defensetheory‘s predictions can be grouped in two broad types, prime predictions and explanatory predictions.The theory’sprime predictions derive from its prime hypothesis (“War is more likely when conquestis easy“;or, for the theory‘s perceptualvariant, “Waris more likelywhen statesthink conquest is easy”).Tests of these predictions shed light on whether offense dominance (or perceptions of offense dominance)causes war. Offense-defensetheory‘sexplanatorypredictionsderivefrom the hypotheses that compriseits ten explanations.Tests of these predictionsshed light on both whether and how offense dominance (or perceptions of offense dominance) causes war. PRIME PREDICTIONS. Three prime predictions of offense-defensetheory are tested here. 1. War will be more common in periods when conquest is easy or is believed 2. States that have or believe they have large offensiveopportunitiesor defen- 3. A state will initiate and fight more wars in periods when it has, or thinks easy, less common when conquest is difficult or is believed difficult. sive vulnerabilitieswill initiate and fight more wars than other states. that it has, larger offensive opportunitiesand defensive capabilities. These predictions are tested below in three case studies: Europe since 1789 (treated as a single regional case study), ancient China during the Spring and Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 23 Autumn and Warring Stateseras, and the United States since 1789. I selected these cases because the offense-defense balance (or perceptions of it) varies sharply across time in all three, creating a good setting for ”multiple withincase comparisons” tests that contrast different periods in the same case; because the United States is very secure relative to other countries, creating a good setting for a ”comparison to typical values” tests that contrasts U.S. conduct with the conduct of average states;33and because two of these cases are well recorded (Europesince 1789 and the United States since 1789). The case of Europe since 1789 allows tests of prime predictions 1 and 2.34 We can make crude indices of the offense-defensebalances (actual and perceived) for Europe over the past two centuries, and match them with the incidenceof war (seeTable 1).Offense-defensetheory predicts more war when conquest is easy or is believed easy. We can also estimate the offensive opportunitiesand defensivevulnerabilitiesof individualpowers-for example,since 1789 Prussia/Germany has been more vulnerable and has had more offensive opportunity than Spain, Italy, Britain, or the United States-and can match these estimates with states’ rates of war involvement and war initiation. Offense-defensetheory predicts that states with more defensive vulnerability and offensive opportunity will be more warlike. The ancient China case allows a test of prime prediction 1. The offensedefense balance shifted markedly toward the offense as China’s Spring and Autumn and Warring States periods evolved. Offense-defensetheory predicts a parallel rise in the incidence of warfare during these periods. The U.S. case allows testing of prime predictions 2 and 3. The United States is less vulnerableto foreignmilitarythreats than are other states;hence offensedefense theory predicts that it should start fewer wars and be involved in fewer wars than other states. Americans have also felt more vulnerable to foreign military threats in some eras than in others. The U.S. propensity for war involvement and war initiation should co-vary with this sense of vulnerability. EXPLANATORY PREDICTIONS. Offense-defensetheory posits that offensedominance leads to war through the war-causing action of its ten intervening phenomena A-J: opportunistic expansionism, defensive expansionism, fierce 33. I say more about the logic of within-case comparisonsand comparison to typical values tests in Van Evera, GuidetoMethodsfor Students ofPolitical Science (Ithaca,N.Y.:CornellUniversity Press, 1997),pp. 58-63. O n case selection criteria, see pp. 77-88. 34. In principle, prime prediction 3 could also be tested with this case. This, however, would requiretracing and describing trends ineach state‘ssenseof vulnerability over tim- large task that would fill many pages. Table1.TheOffense-DefenseBalanceamongGreatPowers,17~resmt. MllltaryDiplomaticInaggregateInaggregateAmount realitiesrealitiesmilitaryandmilitaryandofwarfare MilitarywereDiplomaticwerediplomaticdiplomaticamong realitiesthoughtrealitiesthoughtrealitiesrealitiesweregreat Erafavoredtofavorfavoredtofavorfavoredthoughttofavorpowers Pre-1792Defs.Defs.Med.Med.Med.Med.Medium 1792-1815Aggrs.Aggrs.Med.Aggrs.Aggrs.Aggrs.***High 181656Defs.Defs.Defs.Defs.Defs.Defs.Low 1856-71Med.Med.Aggrs.Aggrs.Aggrs.Aggrs.Medium 1871-90Defs.Med.Defs.Defs.Defs.Defs.***Low 1890-1918Defs.Aggrs.Aggrs.Aggrs.Defs.Aggrs.High 1919-45Aggrs.Mixed*Aggrs.Aggrs.**Aggrs.Aggrs.****High 1945-1990sDefs.Med.Defs.Defs.Defs.Defs.***Low Aggrs.:Thefactorfavorsaggressors. Defs.:Thefactorfavorsdefenders. Med.:Amediumvalue:thingsaresomewhereinbetween,cutbothways. Mixed:Somenationalelitessawdefensedominance,somesawoffensedominance. Theperceptionsentriesareanaverageoftheperceptionsofthegreatpowerelites.Insomecases,theperceptionsofthese elitesvariedsharplyacrossstates,forexample,perceptionsofmilitaryrealitiesinthe1930s. Thingsvariedacrossstates.TheGermaneliterecognizedthemilitarypoweroftheoffensiveinthelate1930s;theelitesof othergreatpowersthoughtthedefensewasdominant. **Thingsvariedacrossstates.TheGermanelite(aboveallHitler)exaggeratedtheconsiderableactualdiplomaticweaknessof thedefense;theelitesofothergreatpowersrecognizedthisweaknessbutdidnotoverstateit.Thesebeliefsaveragetoa perceptionofsubstantialdiplomaticoffensedominance. ***Elitesexaggeratedthestrengthoftheoffenseduring1792-1815,1871-90,and1945-1990%butnotbyenoughtogivethe realitiesandperceptionsoftheoffensedefensebalancedifferentscores. ****Whenweaggregateperceptionsoftheoffense-defensebalance,theerrorsofGermanyandtheotherpowerscanceleach otherout.Germany'sexaggerationofthediplomaticpoweroftheoffenseoffsetsotherpowers'exaggerationofthemilitary powerofthedefense,leavinganaggregateperceptionfairlyclosetotheoffense-dominantreality. h, h, ;fi h, bFa Offense,Defense, and the Causes of War I 25 resistance to others’ expansion, first-strike advantages, windows of opportunity and vulnerability, faits accomplisand belligerent reactionsto them, reluctance to solve conflicts through negotiation, policies of secrecy, intense arms racing, and policies that ease conquest, such as offensiveforce postures and offensive alliances. If offense-defense theory is valid, these intervening phenomena should correlate with the real and perceived offense-defensebalance. Two explanatory predictions can be inferred. 1. Phenomena A-J will be more abundant in eras of real or perceived offense dominance: the ten phenomena should increase as offense strengthens and diminish as offense weakens. 2. States that have or believe they have largeoffensiveopportunitiesor defensive vulnerabilities will more strongly embrace policies that embody phenomena A-J.35 Two of the case studies presented here shed light on these explanatory predictions.The case of Europe allows a partial test of both. We can code only two of offense-defense theory’s ten intervening phenomena (IntPs A and B, opportunistic and defensive expansionism) for the whole period. We have fragmentary data for values on the other eight intervening variables. Hence the case lets us test explanationsA and B fairlycompletelyand offersscattered evidence on explanations C-J. To test explanationsA and B, we ask if expansionism correlates over time with periods of real or perceived offense dominance, and if statesthat were (or believed they were) less secureand more able to aggress were more expansionist. The case of the United States since 1789 allows a more complete, if rather weak, test of explanatory prediction 2. TEST 1: EUROPE 1789-1990s A composite measure of the offense-defensebalance in Europe since 1789 can be .fashioned by blending the histories of Europe’s military and diplomatic 35. Explanatory predictions 1 and 2 are inferred from the “leftside” of offensedefense theov, that is, from hypotheses AI-J1, which frame the claim that offense dominance causes intervening phenomena A-J (see Figure 1). Predictions could also be inferred from hypotheses A2-J2,which comprise the ”right side” of the theory, and frame the claim that intervening phenomena A-J cause war. For example, we could infer that (6) warfare will be more common in eras and regions where phenomena A-J are more prevalent, and (7)states that embrace policies that embody phenomena A-J will be involved in more wars and will initiate more wars than other states. I leave “right side” hypotheses untested here because the effects of phenomena A-J are less debated than their causes. Most agree that they cause trouble. International Security 22:4 I 26 offense-defense balances, as outlined above.36 In sum, the offense-defense balance went through six phases comprising three updown oscillations after 1789.Conquestwas never easy in an absolute sense during these twocenturies. Conquest was, however, markedly easier during 1792-1815, 1856-71, and 1930s-1945 than it was during 1815-56,1871-192Os, and 1945-1990s. Elite perceptions of the offense-defensebalance track these oscillations quite closely,but not exactly. Elites chronicallyexaggerated the power of the offense, but did so far more in some periods than in others. Most important, they greatly exaggerated the power of the offense during 1890-1918: elites then wrongly thought conquest was very easy when in fact it was very hard. Thus the pattern of reality and perception run roughly parallel, with the major exception of 1890-1 918. Tides of war and peace correlate loosely with the offense-defense balance during this period, and tightly with the perceived offense-defense balance. Expansionism and war were more common when conquest was easy than when it was difficult,and were far more common when conquestwas believed easy than when it was believed difficult. Moreover, states that believed they faced large offensive opportunities and defensive vulnerabilities (especially Prussia/Germany) were the largest troublemakers. They were more expansionist, they were involved in more wars, and they started more wars than other states. 1792-1815. During 1792-1815 the offense was fairly strong militarily, as a result of France’s adoption of the popular mass army (enabled by the popularity of the French revolutionary g~vernment).~~Moreover, European elites widely exaggeratedone another’s vulnerability to conquest:at the outset of the War of 1792all three belligerents (France, Austria, and Prussia) thought their 36. My composite index represents my own “author‘s estimates” based on sources provided throughout this article.I measured the actualand perceived Europe-wideoffense-defensebalances by asking:(1) Did military technology,force posture,and doctrinefavorthe offense or the defense? Did elites and publicsbelieve these factorsfavored the offense or the defense?(2) Did geography and the domestic social and political order of states favor the offense or the defense? Did elites and publics believe they favored the offense or defense? (3) How numerous and powerful were balancer states, and how strongly did they balance? Did elites believe that other states would balance or bandwagon? (4)Did defensive alliances form, and did they operate effectively? Did elites believe that they operated effectively? I gave these factors the same rough relative weight they receive in standard historical accounts. 37. A discussionof the military offense-defense balance in this era is Quester, Offense and Defense in the International System, pp. 66-72. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War 1 27 opponents were on the verge of collapse and could be quickly crushed?8 Defense-enhancing diplomacy was sluggish: Britain, Europe's traditional balancer, stood by indifferently during the crisis that produced the War of 1792, issuing a formal declaration of ne~trality.~~Moreover, French leaders underestimated the power of defense-enhancing diplomacy because they widely believed that other states would bandwagon with threats instead of balancing against them.40In short, military factors helped the offense, and this help was further exaggerated; political factors did little to help bolster defenders, and this help was underestimated. 1815-56. After 1815both arms and diplomacy favored defenders, as outlined above. Mass armies disappeared:' British economic power grew, and Britain remained active on the continent as a balancer. Continental powers expected Britain to balance and believed British strength could not be overridden. This defense-dominant arrangement lasted until midcentury.It began weakening before the Crimean War (1853-56). When war in Crimea broke out, military factors still favored defenders, but elites underestimated the power of the defense:Britain and France launched their 1854Crimean offensive in false expectation of quick and easy victory!2 In general, diplomatic factors favored the defense (Britain still balanced actively), but during the prewar crisis in 38. Blanning, Origins of the French Revolutionary Wars, p. 116. Austrian and Prussian leaders were assured that revolutionary France could be quickly smashed. Ibid., p. 114. One Prussian leader advised his officers: "Do not buy too many horses, the comedy will not last long. The army of lawyerswill be annihilatedin Belgium and we shallbe homeby autumn." lbid.,p. 116.Meanwhile, French revolutionarieswrongly expected a pro-French revolutionary uprising of the oppressed peoples of feudal Europe. Ibid., p. 136; R.R. Palmer, World of the French Revolution (New York Harper and Row, 19711, p. 95; and George Rud6, Revolutionary Europe, 1783-1825 (Glasgow:Fontana/Collins, 1964), p. 209. 39. Blanning, Origins of the French Revolutionary Wars, pp. 131-135. 40. As Steven Ross notes, French expansionists thought they could intimidate Europe into coexisting with an expanded French empire in the 1790s: "By inflictingrapid and decisive defeats upon one or more members of the coalition, the [French]directorshoped to rupture allied unity and force individual members to seek a separate peace." Steven T. Ross, European Diplomatic History, 1789-1825 (Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor Doubleday, 19691, p. 186. Later Napoleon thought he could compel Britain to make peace by establishingFrench continental dominion, proclaiming after the Peace of Amiens, "With Europe in its present state, England cannot reasonably make war on us unaided." Geoffrey Bruun, Europe and the French Imperium, 2799-1814 (New York Harper and Row, 1938), p. 118. See also Blanning, Origins of the French Revolutionary Wars, p. 109. 41. On the post-1815 restoration of pre-Napoleonicwarfare, see wester, offense and Defense in the International System, pp. 73-74; and Michael Howard, War in European History (London: Oxford University Press, 1976),pp. 94-95. 42. Richard Smoke, War:Controlling Escalation (Cambridge,Mass.: Harvard UniversityPress, 19771, p. 191. International Security 22:4 I 28 1853, diplomacy favored the offensebecause Britain and France blundered by giving Turkey unconditional backing that amounted to an offensive alliance. This encouraged the Turkish aggressionsthat sparked the war?3 1856-71. After the Crimean War the offense-defense balance shifted further toward the offense. Changes in the military realm cut both ways. Mass armies were appearing (bolstering the offense), but small arms were growing more lethal and railroads were expanding (bolstering the defense).In the diplomatic realm, however, the power of defenders fell dramatically because defenseenhancing diplomacy largely broke down. Most important, Britain entered an isolationist phase that lasted into the 1870s, and Russia lost interest in maintaining the balance among the western powers.44As a result, diplomatic obstacles to continental conquest largely disappeared, giving continental aggressors a fairly open field. This diplomatic change gave France and Sardinia, and then Prussia, a yawning offensive opportunity, which they exploited by launching a seriesof wars of opportunistic expansion-in 1859,1864,1866,and 1870.But defense-enhancingdiplomacy had not disappeared completely, and it helped keep these wars short and limited. In 1859British and Russian neutrality gave France and Sardinia a free hand, which they used to seize Lombardy from Austria.45In 1864 British, Russian, and French neutrality gave Prussia and Austria a free hand, which they used to seize Schleswig-Holstein from Denmark.& In 1866 British, French, and Russian neutrality gave Prussia carte blanche against Austria, which Prussia used to smash Austria and consolidate its control of North germ an^?^ Even after war broke out, major fighting proceeded for weeks before any outside 43. lbid., pp. 167, 179-181, 185; Richard Smoke, “The Crimean War,” in George, Avoiding War, pp. 36-61 at 48-49, 52. The motives of the powers also illustrate offense-defensedynamics.The main belligerents (Britain, France, Russia, and Turkey) were impelled in part by security concerns that would have been allayed had they believed the defensemore dominant.Smoke, War,pp. 149, 155, 158-159,162, 190. 44. The harsh Crimean War settlement Britain imposed on Russia turned it into a non-status quo power. Overthrowingthat settlementbecame Russia’schief aim in Europeandiplomacy, superseding its interest in preserving order to the west. M.S. Anderson, 7% EasfernQuestion, 1774-1923 (London:Macmillan, 19661, pp. 144-146. 45. A.J.E Taylor, The Sfruggle for Mastery in Europe 2848-1918 (London:Oxford University Press, 1970, pp. 108, 110. 46. Ibid., pp. 146-154. Britain would have backed Denmark had it found a continental ally but none was available.Ibid., pp. 146-148. 47. Smoke, War,pp. 85-92. Britain remained in a semi-isolationistmood in 1866,and Napoleon 111 thought Francewould profit fromthe long, mutuallydebilitatingAustro-Prussianwar he expected. Like the Soviets in 1939, Napoleon underestimated the danger of a quick, lopsided victory by either side. Ibid., pp. 87-90. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 29 state even threatened interventi~n.~'As A.J.P. Taylor notes, Bismarck's 1866 diplomatic opportunity-a wide-open field for unopposed expansion-was "unique in recent hist01-y."~~ In 1870 Bismarck ensured the neutrality of the other European powers by shifting responsibility for the war to France and convincing Europe that the war stemmed from French expansionism?' As a result, Prussia again had a free hand to pursue its expansionist aims. It used this to smash France, seize Alsace-Lorraine, and consolidatecontrol over South Germany? 1871-90. For some twenty years after the Franco-Prussian War, the defense dominated because of Bismarck's new diplomacy and Britain's renewed activism. In the military area the cult of the offensive had not yet taken hold. In diplomacy Bismarck wove a web of defensive alliances that deterred aggressors and calmed status quo powers after 1879.52British power waned slightly, but this was offset by the recovery of Britain's will to play the balancer. The "war-in-sight" crisis of 1875 illustrates the change:Britain and Russia together deterred a renewed German attack on France by warning that they would not allow a repeat of 1870-71?3 1890-1919. After 1890 military realities increasingly favored the defense, but elites mistakenly believed the opposite. Diplomaticrealities swung toward the offense, and elites believed they favored the offense even more than they did. 48. Ibid., p. 86. 49. Taylor, Struggle for Mastery, p. 156. Moreover, Bismarck stopped the 1866 war partly because he feared French or Russian intervention if Prussia fought on too long or conquered too much. Smoke, War,pp. 101-102. Thus lack of defense-enhancing diplomacy helped cause the war while Prussian fear of such diplomacy shortened and limited the war. 50. William Carr, The Origins of the Wars of German Unification (London: Longman, 1991), p. 202; and Michael Howard, The Franco-Prussian War: The German Invasion of France, 1870-1871 (New York: Granada, 1961),p. 57. Austria also stayed neutral because Hungarian Magyar influence was growing inside the Dual Monarchy, and the Magyars felt that the more Austria was pushed out of Germany, the stronger the position of the Magyars within it would be. R.R. Palmer and Joel Colton, A History of the Modern World,4th ed. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 19711,p. 574. 51. On Prussia's free hand, see Smoke, War,pp. 133-136; Norman Rich, The Age of Nationalism and Reform, 1850-1890,2d ed.(New York W.W. Norton, 19m, p. 140;and W.E. Mosse, European Powers and the German Question (New York Octagon, 1969), pp. 291,295. 52. Bismarck formed defensive alliances with Austria, Italy, and Romania, and a more limited defensive accord with Russia-specifically, a reciprocal agreement not to join a war against the other unless the other attacked France (in the German case) or Austria (in the Russian case). Synopses include Paul M. Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000 (New York: Random House, 1987), pp. 249-250; and Robert E. &good and Robert W. Tucker, Force, Order, and Justice(Baltimore,Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1967),pp. 8C-81.For a longer account, see Taylor, Struggle for Mastery, pp. 258-280,316-319. 53. Imanuel Geiss, German Foreign Policy, 1871-1914 (Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 19761, p. 28. International Security 22.4 I 30 European militaries were seized by a "cult of the offensive." All the European powers adopted offensive military doctrines, culminating with France's adoption of the highly offensive Plan XVII in 1913 and with Russia's adoption of the highly offensive Plan 20 in 1914. More important, militaries persuaded civilian leaders and publics that the offensedominated and conquestwas easy. As a result, elites and publics widely believed the next war would be quickly won by a decisive offensive. Bismarck'sdefensiveallianceswithered or evolved into defensive-and-offensive alliancesafter he left officein 1890, largelybecause the cult of the offensive made defensive alliances hard to maintain. Pacts conditioned on defensive conductbecame hard to frame because statesdefended by attacking, and status quo powers shrank from enforcing defensive conduct on allies they felt less able to lose. For example, Britain and France felt unable to enforce defensive conduct on a Russian ally that defended by attacking and that they could not afford to see defeated. Elites also thought that aggressors could overrun their victims before allies could intervene to save them, making defensive alliances less effective. Thus Britain seemed less able to save France before Germany overran it, leading Germany to discount British power. Lastly, German leaders subscribed to a bandwagon theory of diplomacy, which led them to underestimate others' resistance to German expansion. Overall, the years before 1914 were the all-time high point of perceived offense dominance. Nine of the ten intervening phenomena predicted by offense-defensetheory (all except phenomenon G, nonnegotiation) flourished in this world of assumed offense dominance. Opportunistic and defensive expansionist ideas multiplied and spread, especially in Germany. Russia and France mobilized their armies preemptively in the 1914 July crisis. That crisis arose from a fait accompli that Germany and Austria instigated in part to shut a looming window of vulnerability. This window in turn had emerged from a land arms race that erupted during 1912-14. The powers enshrouded their military and political plans in secrecy-a secrecy that fostered crisis-managementblunders during July 1914. These blunders in turn evoked rapid, violent reactions that helped drive the crisis out of control. Belief in the offense fueled offensive military doctrines throughout the continent and impeded efforts to restrain allies. Together these dangers formed a prime cause of the war: they bore the 1914 July crisis and helped make it uncontrollable. 191945. The interwar years were a mixed bag, but overall the offense gained the upper hand by 1939, and the German elite believed the offense even stronger than in fact it was. Offense,Defense,and the Causes of War 1 31 Military doctrine and technology gave the defense the advantage until the late 1930s, when German blitzkrieg doctrine combined armor and infantry in an effective offensive combination. This offensive innovation was unrecognized outside Germany and doubted by many in Germany, but the man who counted most, Adolf Hitler, firmly believed in it. This reflected his faith in the offense as a general principle, imbibed from international social Darwinist propaganda in his y0uth.5~ More important, the workings of interwar diplomacy opened a yawning political opportunity for Nazi expansion. Britain fell into a deep isolationism that left it less willing to commit this declining power to curb continental aggre~sors.5~The United States also withdrew into isolation, removing the counterweight that checked Germany in 1918?6 The breakup of AustriaHungary in that year created a new diplomatic constellationthat further eased German expansion. Austria-Hungary would have balanced against German 54. Hitler often echoed international social Darwinist slogans on the short, precarious lives of states, for example, ”Politics is in truth the execution of a nation‘s struggle for existence,” and “Germanywill either be a world power or there will be no Germany.” Quoted in P.M.H. Bell, The Origins of the Second World War in Europe (London: Longman, 1986), p. 81; and in Anthony P. Adamthwaite, TheMaking of the Second World War(London:GeorgeAllenand Unwin, 1977),p. 119. Hitler‘s faith in the offensive differed from that of the pre-1914 cultists of the offensivein three ways. First, he saw offensive capabilities arising from a long search for offensive methods, not from permanent properties of war. In his mind offense could be created, but also had to be; Germany would discover offensive answers only after a long effort. In contrast, the pre-1914 cultiststhought offense inherentlyeasier than defense; deep thought need not be given to how to make it superior, because it alreadywas. Second,Hitler’s offensive optimism was based on racism and soda1 prejudice, as well as on assessment of military factors. Specifically, his contempt for Slavs and Jews led him to expect that the Soviets would quickly collapse under German attack. Third, Hitler’s concerns for German security focused on fear of conquest by economic strangulation, not conquestby French or Sovietblitzkrieg. He thought German securitywas precarious,but for reasonsrooted more in the politicaleconomyof war than in the nature of doctrineor weaponry. These differencesaside, the logical implications of Hitler‘s offensive cult were the same as those of the pre-1914 cult. He exaggerated both German insecurity and the feasibility of imperial solutions to redress it. 55. Prime Minister Neville Chamberlain of Great Britain said in 1937that he ”did not believe we could, or ought . . . to enter a Continentalwar with the intentionof fightingon the same lines as in the last,” meaningthat Britain would deploy no largeground force on the continent.Bell, Origins of the Second World War in Europe, p. 177. Britain had only two divisions available to send to the continent during the 1938Munich crisis, and the four-division force it actually sent in 1939was smaller and less well trained than its small expeditionaryforce of 1914.These four divisions were a drop in the bucket relative to the 84 French and 103 German divisions then deployed. Ibid., p. 175. 56. The United States also proclaimed this isolationism in four neutrality laws passed during 1935-39, giving Hitler a clear if misleading signal of American indifferenceto his aggression.On these laws a synopsis is Thomas A. Bailey, A Diplomatic History of the American People, 9th ed. (EnglewoodCliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall,1974),pp. 701-702,715. International Security 22:4 1 32 expansion, but its smaller successor states tended to bandwag0n.5~This let Hitler extend German influence into southeast Europe by intimidation and subversion. The Soviet Union and the Western powers failed to cooperate against Hitler.%Ideologicalhostility divided them. Britain also feared that a defensive alliance against Hitler would arouse German fears of allied encirclement, spurring German aggressiveness.This chilled British enthusiasm for an AngloFrench-Soviet alliance.59 Hitler exaggerated the already-large advantage that diplomacy gave the offense because he thought bandwagoning prevailed over balancing in international affairs. This false faith colored all his political forecasts and led him to vastly underestimate others states’resistance to his aggressions. Before the war he failed to foresee that Britain and France would balance German power by coming to Poland’s rescue.6oOnce the war began he believed Germany could intimidate Britain into seeking alliance with Germany after Germany crushed France-or, he later held, after Germany smashed the Soviet Union.61 He thought the United States could be cowed into staying neutral by the 1940 German-Japanesealliance (the alliance had the opposite effect, spurring U.S. intervention)?’ In short, Hitler’s false theories of diplomacy made three of his most dangerous opponents shrink to insignificance in his mind. These realities and beliefs left Hitler to face temptations like those facing Bismarck in 1866and 1870. Hitler thought he could conquer his victims seriatim. He also thought his conquests would arouse little countervailing opposition from distant neutral powers.63As a result, he believed he faced a yawning opportunity for aggression. 57. Explainingwhy weaker states are more prone to bandwagon than are stronger states is Walt, Origins of AKunces, pp. 29-30. 58. Bell, Origins of the Second World War in Europe, pp. 172, 224, 260; and Adamthwaite,Making of the Second World War, pp. 60,69. This failure greatly eased Hitler’s aggressions,because geography made Britain‘s 1939 guarantees to Poland and Romania unenforceable without a Soviet alliance. Ibid., pp. 86, 91. 59. RaymondJ. Sontag,A Broken World, 2929-2939 (New York: Harper and Row, 1971),p. 361. 60. On August 22, 1939, Hitler assured his generals that “the West will not intervene” to defend Poland. Jeremy Noakes and Geoffrey Pridham, eds., Nazism, 1919-1945: A History in Documents and Eyewitness Accounts, 2 vols. (New York Schocken Books, 1988),vol. 2, p. 741. 61. See Jack Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991),p. 94. 62. Noakes and Pridham, Nazism, vol. 2, p. 797. Some German leaders also hoped that Germany could win decisively in Europe before the United States could bring its power to bear. Thus in September 1940 Hitler‘s naval commander in chief voiced the hope that Britain could be beaten “before the United States is able to intervene effectively.” Ibid., p. 794. 63. The fine-grainedpattern of events during 1938-40-who attacked whom and when-also fits the predictionsof offense-defensetheory (specifically,prime prediction 3).The Western alliesstood offense, Defense, and the Causes of war I 33 Unlike 1914, the late 1930s were not a pure case of perceived offense dominance. Instead, the 1930s saw status quo powers’ perceptions of defense dominance create real offensive opportunities for an aggressor state. Hitler thought the offense strong and even exaggerated its strength, but other powers (the Soviet Union, Britain, and France) underestimated its strength. Their percep tions of defense dominance relaxed their urge to jump the gun at early signs of threat (as Russia did in 1914); this made things safer. But this perception also relaxed their will to balance Germany,because they found German expansion less frightening. This weakened the coalition against Hitler, leaving him wider running room.@ 1945-1990s. After 1945 two changes swung the offense-defense balance back toward the defense. First, the end of American isolationismtransformed European political affairs. The United States replaced Britain as continental balancer, bringing far more power to bear in Europe than Britain ever had. As a result, Europe in the years after 1945 was unusually defense dominant from a diplomatic standpoint. Second, the nuclear revolution gave defenders a large military advantage so large that conquest among great powers became virtually impossible. Conquest now required a nuclear first-strike capability (the capacity to launch a nuclear strike that leaves the defender unable to inflict unacceptable damage in retaliation). Defenders could secure themselves merely by maintaining a second-strike capability (the capacity to inflict unacceptable damage on the attacker’s society after absorbing an all-out strike). The characteristicsof nuclear weapons-their vast power, small size, light weight, and low costensured that a first-strike capability would be very hard to attain, while a second-strikecapability could be sustained at little cost. As a result, the great powers became essentiallyunconquerable, and even lesser powers could now stand against far stronger enemies. Overall, the nuclear revolution gave defenders an even more lopsided advantage than the machine gun-barbed wireentrenchments-railroad complex that emerged before 1914. without attacking Germany in 1938 and again in 193940 because they doubted they could win a decisive victory.Germany stood without attacking westward in the fall of 1939 for the same reason, and finally attacked in May 1940 after German military leaders developed a plausible plan for decisive attack. Mearsheimer, Conventional Deterrence, pp. 67-133. 64. Would the risk of war have fallen had all powers believed the offense was dominant in the late 1930s?Thisseems unlikely.The status quo powers would have balanced harder against Hitler, offering him more discouragement, but they also would have been jumpier, making early crises more dangerous. One of these crises-Hitler’s remilitarization of the Rhineland, the Spanish civil war, or the German seizure of Austria or Czechoslovakia-probably would have served as the “Sarajevo” for World War 11, with the Allies moving first as Russia did in 1914. International Security 22:4 134 American and Soviet policymakers grasped thiscosmic military revolution only slowly, however. At first many feared nuclear weapons would be a boon to aggressors. When this fear proved false, the vast advantage they gave defenders was only dimly recognized, partly because scholarsstrangely failed to explain it. Thus the nuclear revolution changed realities far more than they did perceptions. As a result, state behavior changed only slowly, and both superpowers competed far harder-in both Central Europe and the third world-than objective conditions warranted. The Cold War was far more peacefulthan theprecedingfortyyears, but could havebeen stillmorepeaceful had Soviet and US.elites understood that their security problems had vastly diminished and were now quite small. In sum, the events of 1789-1990s clearly corroborate offense-defensetheory predictions-specifically, prime predictions 1 and 2, as well as both explanatory predictions. These conclusions rest on rather sketchy data-especially regarding the explanatory predictions-but that data confirm offense-defense theory so clearly that other data would have to be very different to reversethe result. 0 The incidence of war correlatesloosely with the offense-defensebalance and very tightly with perceptions of the offense-defensebalance (for a summary see Table 1). Europe’s less-secure and more offensively capable continental powers were perennial troublemakers, while more secure and less offensively capable offshore powers were perennial defenders of the status quo. Prussia/Germany was cursed with the least defensible borders and faced the most offensive temptations. It started the largest number of major wars (1864, 1866,1914,1939, and shared responsibilityfor 1870with France).France and Russia, with more defensible borders and fewer temptations, started fewer major wars.65Britain and the United States,blessed with even more insulating borders, joined a number of European wars but started none.&Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland, also insulated from other powers by mountains or oceans, fought very little. Thus the timing of war and the identities of the belligerents tightly fit prime predictions 1 and 2. 65.France can be assigned prime responsibility for 1792 and 1859,and shared responsibilityfor Crimea and 1870.Russia deserves primeresponsibilityfor the ColdWar and shared responsibility for Crimea and the 190445Russo-JapaneseWar. 66. Britain does share responsibility for the Crimean War with Russia, France, and Turkey. Offense,Defense, and the Causes of War I35 0 Sketchy evidence suggests that opportunistic and defensive expansionism were more prominent during the periods of perceived offense dominance (1792-1815, 1859-71,1890-1914,1930~-1945)than at other times. The years 1792-1815 saw a strong surge of French expansionism, nearly matched at the outset by parallel Prussian e~pansionism.6~The mid-nineteenth century saw large opportunistic expansionism in Prussia and some French expansionism. The years 1890-1914 saw vast expansionist ambitions develop in Wilhelmine Germany6*matched by fierce resistance to this German expansionism in Russia and France, and by lesser French and Russian expansionism. Large German expansionism then reappeared under the Nazis in the 1930s.During other periodsEuropeanexpansionismwas more muted:European powers had smaller ambitions and acted on them less often. This supports explanatory prediction 1. 0 Opportunistic and defensive expansionism were prominent among those statesthat saw the clearest defensivevulnerability and offensiveopportunity (especiallyPrussia/Germany, also revolutionary France), while being more muted among states with more secure borders and fewer offensive opportunities (Britain, the United States, the Scandinavianstates, and Spain).This corroboratesexplanatory prediction 2. How strong is this test? The strength of a passed test depends on the uniqueness of the predictions tested. Do other theories predict the outcome observed, or is the prediction unique to the tested theory? The predictions tested here seem quite unique. There is no obvious competingexplanation for the periodicupsurges and downsurgesin European expansionismand warfare outlined above.Offense-defensetheory has the field to itself.Particular domestic explanations have been offered to explain the aggressiveness of specific states-for example, some argue that Wilhelmine Germany was aggressive because it was a late industrializer, that revolutionary France was aggressive becauseitsregime cameto power through mass revolution,and sof~rth~~-but no competing theory claims to explain the general cross-time and cross-state pattern of war involvement that we observe. Hence this test seems strong. What importance does thisevidence assign to offense-defensetheory?That is, how potent is offense dominance as a cause of war? In Europe since 1789, the nature of international relations has gyrated sharply with shifts in the 67. On Prussia's expansionism, see Blanning, Origins of the French Revolutionary Wars, pp. 72-82; on French expansionism,see ibid., passim. 68. A summary of WilhelmineGerman aims and policies is Geiss, German Foreign Policy. 69. On Germany as late industrializer,see Snyder,Myths of Empire, pp. 66-111; and on France as a revolutionary state, see Walt, Revolution and War,pp. 46-128. International Security 22:4 I36 perceived offense-defense balance. War is far more common when elites believe that the offense dominates, and states are far more belligerent when they perceive large defensive vulnerabilities and offensive opportunities for themselves. This indicates that perceptions of the offense-defense balance have a large impact on international relations. Offense-defense theory is important as well as valid. How much history does this evidence suggest that offense-defense theory can explain? Explanatory power is partly a function of the prevalence of the theory's cause: abundant causes explain more history than scarce causes. In Europe since 1789 the offense has seldom been really strong, but it was believed strong quite often-often enough to cause considerable trouble. TEST 2: ANCIENT CHINA The ancient Chinese multistate system witnessed a long-term shift from defense dominance to offense dominance across the years 722-221 BCE.70 Offense-defense theory predicts that warfare should have increased as this transformation unfolded (see prime prediction 1). This prediction is fulfilled: diplomacygrew markedly more savage and international relationsgrew markedly more violent as the power of the offense increased. Before roughly 550 BCE the defense held the upper hand among China's many feudal states. Four related changes then strengthened the offense: feudalism declined:* mass infantry replaced chariots as the criticalmilitary force, conscriptionwas introduced, and armies grew tremendously in size.n The two largest Chinese states deployed enormous armies of more than a million men, and somesmaller states had armiesnumbering in the hundreds of thousands.73 As armies grew, border forts had less stopping power against infantry because invaders could sweep past, leaving a smaller portion of their force behind to besiege the forts. Forts also lost stopping power as improved siege-engines appeared-battering rams, catapults, and rolling towers-that further eased the conquest of fortified positions.74The decline of feudalism eased offensive operations by reducing social stratification, which increased troop loyalty to 70. Concurringis Andreski, Military Organization and Society, p. 76. 71. Noting the decline of feudalism are Samuel B. Griffiths, "Introduction,"in Sun Tzu, The Art of War (London:Oxford University Press, 1971),p. 33; and Dun J. Li, The Ageless Chinese: A History, 3d ed.(New York: Charles Scribner's Sons, 19781, p. 64. 72. On the growth of armies, the introduction of conscription, and the rise of infantry, see Li, Ageless Chinese, p. 56; Griffiths, "Introduction,"pp. 28, 33; and Wolfram Eberhard, A History of China (Berkeley:University of California Press, 19m, p. 49. 73. Li, Ageless Chinese, p. 56. 74. Andreski, Military Organization and Society, p. 76. Offense,Defense, und the Causes of War I 37 regimes; this meant troops could be trusted to conduct long-distanceoffensive operations without deserting. The outcomes of battles and wars reveal the shift toward the offense that these technical and social changes produced. The number of independent Chinese states declined from two hundred in the eighth century BCE to seven in the late fifth century, to one in the late third century-a clear measure of the growing power of the offense.75Before550 BCE defenders were often victorious. Thus the states of Tsin and Ch’i fought three great battles, in 632,598, and 567 BCE, each won by the defender.Dun J. Li concludes,”If the three battles indicate anything, they meant that neither side was able to challenge successfully the other‘s leadership in its own sphere of infl~ence.”~~In contrast, the state of Ch’in conquered all of China in a rapid campaign lasting only nine years at the end of the Warring States period (230-221 B C E ) . ~ This increasein the power of the offense coincideswith a stark deterioration in international relations. During the Springand Autumn period (722453 BCE) interstate relations were fairly peaceful, and wars were limited by a code of conduct. The code confined warfare to certain seasons of the year and forbade killing enemy wounded. It was considered wrong to stoop to deceit, to take unfair advantage of adversaries, to ”ambush armies,” or to “massacrecities.“78 The subsequent WarringStatesperiod (453-221 BCE) was perhaps the bloodiest era in Chinese history. Warfare raged almost constantlyn becoming a “fundamental occupation” of states.*’ Restraints on warfare were abandoned. Casualties ran into hundreds of thousands, and prisoners of war were massacred en masse.81Diplomatic conduct deteriorated; one historian writes that “diplomacy was based on bribery, fraud, and deceit.”@ In short, the shift toward offense dominance in China during 722-221 BCE correlates tightly with a dramatic breakdown of China’s international order. TEST 3: UNITED STATES 1789-1990s Since 1815 the United States has been by far the most secure of the world’s great powers, blessed with two vast ocean moats, no nearby great powers, and 75. Li, Ageless Chinese,pp. 50, 59. 76. Ibid., p. 52. 77. Ibid., p. 59. 78. Griffiths,“Introduction,”p. 30. 79. Ibid., p. 21. 80. Ibid., p. 24, quoting Shang Yang, Prime Minister of Chin, who conceived war and agriculture to be the two fundamental occupations. 81. Li, Ageless Chinese, pp. 56, 58-59. 82. Griffiths, “Introduction,”p. 24. International Security 22:4 I 38 (after 1890)the world’s largest economy. In the nineteenth century the United States also had substantial offensive opportunities, embodied in chances for continental and then Pacific expansion against weak defenders. However, America’s security endowments were quite extraordinary, while its offensive opportunities were more ordinary. Offense-defense theory predicts that such a state will exhibit perhaps average offensiveopportunism but markedly less defensive belligerence than other states. Hence, on net, it will start fewer wars and be involved in fewer wars than others (see prime prediction 2). This forecast is confirmed, although not dramatically, by the pattern of past U.S. foreign policy. The United Stateshas fought other great powers only three times in its two hundred-year history-in 1812,1917, and 1941-a low count for a great power.83The 1812war stemmed mainly from US. belligerence,but the wars of 1917 and 1941 resulted mainly from others‘ belligerence. The United States did start some of its lesser wars (1846 and 18981, but it joined other wars more reactively (Korea and Vietnam). Offense-defensetheory also predicts that while the United Stateswill pursue some opportunistic expansionism (intervening phenomenon A), it will embrace few policies that embody offense-defense theory’s other intervening phenomena 03-J) (explanatory prediction 2). Where the record allows judgments, this forecast is borne out. Regarding expansionism, the United States has confined itself largelyto opportunistic imperialism against frailopponents. Defensive expansionismhas been muted, and overall, expansionistideas have held less sway in the United States than in other powers. This is reflected in the relatively small size of the U.S. empire. The modern American empire has been limited to a few formal colonies seized from Spain in the 1890s and an informal empire in the Caribbean/Central American area, with only intermittent control exerted more widely-a zone far smaller than the vast empires of the European powers. The U.S. impulse to engage in preemptive and preventive war has been small. In sharp contrast to Germany and Japan, the United Stateshas launched a stealthy first strike on another major power just once (in 1812) and has jumped through only one window of opportunity (in 1812). Surprise first strikes and window-jumping were considered on other occasions(e.g.,preventive war was discussed during 1949-54, and surprise attack on Cuba was considered during the Cuban missile crisis), but seldom seriously. 83. Britain, France, Russia, and hssia/Germany fought other great powers an average of five times over the same two hundred years, by my count.None fought as few as three times. Offense,Defense, and the Causes of War I 39 American diplomacy has been strikingly free of fait accomplitactics. American foreign and security policy has generally been less secretive than those of the European continental powers, especially during the late Cold War, when the United States published military data that most powers would highly classify as state secrets.The U.S. arms raced with the SovietUnion energetically during the Cold War, but earlier maintained very small standing military forces-far smaller than those of other great powers. Overall, intervening phenomena B-J of offense-defensetheory are strikinglyabsent in the U.S. case. In sum, the United States has not been a shrinking violet, but it has been less bellicose than the average great power. Compare, for example, U.S. conduct with the far greater imperial aggressions of Athens, Rome, Carthage, Spain, Prussia/Germany, Japan, Russia, and France. Offense-defense theory further predicts that levels of American bellicosity should vary inversely with shifts over time in America's sense of security and directlywith the scope of perceived external threats (see prime prediction 3)as in fact they have. During 1789-1815 the United States saw large foreign threats on its borders and large opportunities to dispel them with force.It responded with a bellicose foreign policy that produced the 1812 war with Britain. During 1815-1914 the United States was protected from the threat of a Eurasian continental hegemon by Britain's active continental balancing, and protected from extracontinental European expansion into the Western hemisphere by the British fleet, which was the de facto enforcer of the Monroe Doctrine. The United Statesresponded by withdrawing from European affairs and maintaining very small standing military forces, although it did pursue continental expansion before 1898 and limited overseas imperial expansion after 1898. During 1914-91 Britain could no longer maintain the European balance. This deprived the United States of its shield against continental European aggressors.Then followed the great era of American activism-fitful at first (191743, then steady and persistent (1947-91). This era ended when the Soviet threat suddenly vanished during 1989-91. After 1991 the United States maintained its security alliances, but reduced its troops stationed overseas and sharply reduced its defense effort. WHAT THESE TESTS INDICATE Offense-defensetheory passed the tests these three cases pose. Are these tests positive proof for the theory or mere straws in the wind? International Security 22:4 I 40 We learn more from strong tests than from weak ones. The strength of a passed test is a function of the uniqueness of the predictions that the test corroborated. The more numerous and plausible are contending explanations for the patterns that the test theory predicted and the test revealed, the weaker the test. The three case study tests reported here range from fairly weak to quite strong. They each lack Herculean power but in combinationthey pose a strong test. The test posed by the ancient China case is weak because our knowledge of ancient Chinese society and politics is fairly thin. This leaves us unable to rule out competing explanations for the rise of warfare in the Warring States period that point to causes other than the rise of offense. The test posed by the U.S. case is a little stronger but still rather weak overall. Alternative explanations for the rise and fall of American global activism are hard to come up with, leaving the offense-defensetheory’s explanation without strong competitors, so this element of the test posed by the U.S. case is fairly strong. Plausible contending explanations for other aspects of the U.S. case can be found, however. For example, some would argue that America’s more pacific conduct is better explained by its democratic domestic structure than by its surfeit of security.Others would contend that the United States has fewer-than-average conflicts of interest with other powers because it shares no borders with them, and it fights fewer wars for this reason. Hence this element of the test posed by the U.S. case is weak: US.lower-than-averagebellicosity is only a straw in the wind. As noted above, the case of Europe since 1789offersa fairly strong test. Some competingexplanationsfor Germany’sgreater bellicosityare offered-as noted above, the lateness of German industrialization is sometimes suggested as an alternative cause, as is German culture. However, there is no obvious plausible competing explanation for the main pattern we observe in the case-the rise of warfare during 1792-1815,1856-71, and 1914-45,and the greater periods of peace in between. The fit of this pattern with prime prediction 1of offense-defense theory lends it strong corroboration. WHAT PRESCRIPTIONS FOLLOW? If offense dominance is dangerous, policies that control it should be pursued. Governments should adopt defensive military force postures and seek arms control agreements to limit offensive forces. Governments should also maintain defensivealliances.American securityguarantees in Europeand Asia have made conquest much harder since 1949 and have played a major role in Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 42 preserving peace. A U.S. withdrawal from either region would raise the risk of conflict. Conclusion: Offense-Defense Theory in Perspecfive Offense-defensetheory has the attributes of a good theory. First, it has three elementsthat give a theory claim to large explanatorypower. (1)Large importance, that is, its posited cause has large effects. Variance in the perceived offense-defense balance causes large variance in the incidence of warfare. Variance in the actual offense-defensebalance has less impact because policymakers often misperceive it, but it has a potent effect when policymakers perceive it accurately.(2)Wide explanatoryrange. The theory explains results acrossmany domains of behavior-in military policy, foreign policy, and crisis diplomacy.84It governs many intervening phenomena (e.g., expansionism, first-move advantage, windows, secrecy, negotiation failures, crisis management blunders, arms races, tight alliances) that have been seen as important war causes in their own right. Thus offense-defense theory achievessimplicity, binding a number of war causes under a single rubric. Many causes are reduced to one cause with many effects. (3)Wide real-world applicability.Real offense dominance is rare in modern times, but the perception of offense dominance is fairly widespread. Therefore, if perceived offense dominance causes war it causes lots of war, and offense-defensetheory explainsmuch of international history. Second, offense-defensetheory has large prescriptive utility, because the offense-defense balance is affected by national foreign and military policy; hence it is subject to political will. Perceptions of the offensedefense balance are even more malleable, being subject to correction through argument. Both are far more manipulable than the polarity of the international system, the strength of international institutions, the state of human nature, or other war causes that have drawn close attention. Third,offense-defensetheory is quitesatisfymg,althoughit leaves important questions unanswered. In uncovering the roots of its ten interveningphenom- 84. Moreover, offense-defense theory might be usefully adapted for application beyond the domain of war, for example, to explain internationaleconomiccompetition(orcooperation),or even intra-academic competition. Suggesting its application to economics is JitsuoTsuchiyama, who writes of the "prosperitydilemma''-a cousin of the security dilemma in which measures taken by one state to increaseits economic well-being decreaseanother's economic well-being.SeeJitsuo Tsuchiyama, "The US.-JapanAlliance after the Cold War: End of the Alliance?" unpublished manuscript,O h Institute, Harvard University, 1994, p. 27. International Security 224 I 42 ena, offense-defensetheory offers a more satisfying (and simpler) explanation than do interpretations pointing directly to these phenomena.However, it also raises another mystery: Why is the strength of the offense so often exagger- ated? Historysuggeststhat offensedominanceis at the same time dangerous,quite rare, and widely overstated.It further suggests that this exaggeration of insecurity, and the bellicose conduct it fosters, are prime causes of national insecurity and war. Statesare seldomas insecureas they think they are. Moreover, if they are insecure,this insecurityoften grows from their own efforts to escape imagined insecurity. The rarity of real insecurity is suggested by the low death rate of modern great powers. In ancient times great powers often disappeared, but in modern times (since1789)no great powers have permanently lost sovereignty,and only twice (Francein 1870-71 and in 1940) has any been even temporarily overrun by an unprovoked aggre~sor.’~Both times Francesoonregained its sovereignty through the intervention of outside powers-illustrating the powerful defensive influence of great-power balancing behavior. The prevalence of exaggerationsof insecurity is revealed by the great wartime enduranceof many statesthat enter wars for securityreasons, and by the aftermath of the world’s great security wars, which often reveal that the belligerents’ security fears were illusory. Athens fought Sparta largely for securityreasons, but held out for a full nine years (413-404 BCE) after suffering the crushing loss of its Sicilian expedition-an achievement that shows the falsehood of its original fears. Austria-Hungary held out for a full four years under allied battering during 1914-18, a display of toughness at odds with its own prewar self-image of imminent collapse. With twenty-twenty hindsight we can now see that modem Germany would have been secure had it only behaved itself. Wilhelmine Germany was Europe’s dominant state, with Europe’s largest and fastest-growing economy.It faced no plausible threats to its sovereigntyexcept those it created by its own belligerence.Later, interwar Germany and Japan could have secured themselves simply by moderating their conduct. This would have assured them of allies, hence of the raw materialssuppliesthey sought to seizeby force.America’saggressiveand often costly Cold War interventions in the third world now seem hypervigilant in light of the defensive benefits of the nuclear revolution,America’s geographic 85. France helped trigger the 1870 war; hence one could argue for removing France in 1870 from the list of unprovoking victims of conquest, leaving only France in 1940. Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War I 43 invulnerability,and the strength of third world nationalism, which precluded the Soviet third world imperialism that U.S. interventions sought to prevent. Paradoxically, a chief source of insecurity in Europe since medieval times has been this falsebelief that securitywas scarce.Thisbelief was a self-fulfilling prophecy, fostering bellicose policies that left all states less secure. Modern great powers have been overrun by unprovoked aggressors only twice, but they have been overrun by provoked aggressorssix times-usually by aggressors provoked by the victim’s fantasy-driven defensive bellicosity. Wilhelmine and Nazi Germany, Imperial Japan, Napoleonic France, and Austria-Hungary were all destroyed by dangers that they created by their efforts to escape from exaggerated or imaginary threats to their safety? If so, the prime threat to the security of modern great powers is . . . themselves. Their greatest menace lies in their own tendency to exaggerate the dangers they face, and to respond with counterproductive belligerence. The causes of this syndrome pose a large question for students of international relations. 86. Mussolini also provoked his own destruction, but his belligerencewas not security driven.