Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1986318 Judicial Review and Political Bias: Moving from Consensual to Majoritarian Democracy∗ Nuno Garoupa University of Illinois Urbana Champaign Veronica Grembi Catholic University of Milan PRELIMINARY DRAFT Abstract Due to the collapse of the party system during the mid-nineties, Italy represents an interesting case study to test the effects of a moving from a consensual to a majoritarian democracy on judicial behavior at the level of the Constitutional Supreme Court. Using a dataset of 779 main reviews (ricorsi in via principale) from 1985 to 2005, and proposing new measures of political alignment within constitutional review, we analyze the effect of a change in the political party system on judicial behavior. We preliminarily find that the ruling of a majoritarian democracy tend to produce more political aligned decisions than in a consensual democracy. JEL codes: K0 Keywords: Electoral Rules, Party Systems, Judicial Behavior, Italian Constitutional Court, Judicial Politics ∗ We thank Decio Coviello, Tommaso Nannicini, and the participants of the 2011 Italian Association of Law and Economics Annual Meeting for their insightful comments. We also thank Andrea Di Miceli and Paola Bertoli for excellent research assistance. Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1986318 1 Introduction Several theories compete to explain judicial decision-making: formalist theory, attitudinal model, and various versions of agency theories.1 Formalists take the stance that judges simply interpret and apply the constitution and the law in a conformist view of precedents. Judges are largely guided by what the law says and abide by a strict legal authoritative interpretation. Quite differently, the attitudinal model sees judicial preferences, with special emphasis on ideology, as the main explanatory model (judges have a particular disposition and decide accordingly). Finally, agency theorists recognize the importance of judicial preferences but argue that they are implemented taking into account political and institutional realities (judges are willing to sacrifice their disposition in order to achieve other relevant goals). This large literature has made significant contributions to the understanding of judicial behavior, both theoretically and empirically. Notwithstanding, this literature is largely US based and tends to ignore relevant aspects of a more civil law oriented environment. There is a growing empirical contribution investigating judicial behavior at the Supreme Court outside the US, with notable applications in Europe2 and North America3 , in Asia4 , and in Latin America.5 We propose a further empirical contribution to this literature, which exploits a shock to the reference political system. Our tests allows us to check whether or not a move from a more fuzzy to a deeper clear cut system of political alliances have any impact of judicial behavior in terms of partisanship. Lijphart (1999) has proposed two models of democracy, consensual and majoritarian.6 In the consensual model, there is no clear political polarization; politics is fundamentally based on bargaining, compromise, and inclusiveness. In the majoritarian model, political parties are strongly polarized; politics is settled on significant competition, exclusivity, and straight opposition.7 Our hypothesis is that a majoritarian model polarizes judicial behavior, creating a division within the judiciary that reflects the party system (based on or organized around two coalitions). The consensual model, by contrast, favors 1 See, among others, Brenner and Spaeth (1988), Segal and Cover (1989), George and Epstein (1992), Epstein and Knight (1998), Segal and Spaeth (2002), Hansford and Springgs II (2006), Lax and Cameron (2007). 2 Schneider (2005), Vanberg (2005), Amaral Garcia et. al. (2009), Franck (2009 and 2010), Garoupa et. al. (2013) 3 Tate and Sittiwong (1989), Alarie and Green (2008), Green and Alarie (2009) 4 Ramseyer and Rasmusen (2003), Ramseyer and Rasmusen (2006), Ginsburg (2003), Garoupa et. al. (2011), Escresa and Garoupa (2012) 5 Chavez (2004), Helmke (2004), Iaryczower et. al. (2002 and 2006), Hilbink (2007), Kapiszewski and Taylor (2008), Carroll and Tiede (2011). 6 Notice that in his classical book he considers the role of constitutional review. He establishes a correlation between the degree of judicial review and constitutional flexibility which in turn is related to the party and electoral systems. However, he simply assumes that constitutional review is performed by an independent third party and does not recognize the possible relationship between party system and judicial behavior. Ginsburg (2003) provides an identical discussion in the context of East Asia. 7 The political economy literature has long ago recognized the relationship between electoral rules (party systems) and the behavior of political agents. See, among others Myerson (1993); Persson and Tabellini (1999 and 2000); Lizzeri and Persico (2001); Milesi-Ferretti et al. (2002). 1 Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1986318 compromise and agreement within the judiciary. Our hypothesis can be understood both by a selection effect as well as incentives which reinforce each other. A majoritarian model induces the coalitions to select individuals that are perceived to be loyal (by mere coincidence of preferences). These coalitions are also the natural audience for the justices who can be potentially compensated at later stage by exhibiting loyalty. Therefore, we expect to have political labels such as socialist or conservative to describe judges. In a consensual model, appointments are likely to be more negotiated within the stable coalition and result in individual who are perceived to be faithful to model (that is, favor consensus over dissent). The absence of strong factions also shapes the natural audience and possible rewards. Notice we are not saying that judges are more or less politicized under one particular model by comparison with the alternative model. In both models, consensual and majority, they are likely to be equal responsive to political variables. The point is that the response is revealed in different ways. In particular, we expect more explicit political alignment in a majoritarian model than in a consensual model. To investigate such hypothesis, we use a dataset on Italian Constitutional Court decisions from 1985 to 2005, focusing on decisions concerning main reviews (ricorsi in via principale). The Italian case is quite interesting since Italy was a consensual democracy until 1992 (with a proportional electoral system and a multiparty arrangement stabilized around a stable coalition of five parties that ruled since WWII) and emerged as a majoritarian democracy after 1996 (with plurality rule for electing the parliament and two well defined coalitions that alternated in power). Our preliminary results provide significant support to our hypothesis. We detect more political alignment between the decision of the Court and the political majority after 1996, thus confirming a more polarized judicial behavior. Before 1992, we have no evidence of important political divisions in the Court and the evidence seems to indicate a more consensual judicial behavior. 2 The Institutional Framework 2.1 The Party System Break The move from a First to a Second Republic took place in Italy without a formal constitutional reform, rather it was due to a political scandal burnt out in spring 1992 which has been called the Clean Hands (Mani Pulite) scandal. This scandal addressed a funding parties system extremely expensive and as well outside the realm of legality, and hit to death the coalition of parties at the government both at the national and the regional level.8 That coalition, based on a proportional electoral rule system, has been defined by some political scientists as a polarized pluralist systems [Sartori (1966 and 1976)], whereas others found it a multiparty system with a dominant party [Lijpart (1999)] or an imperfect two-party system [Galli (1966)]. Behind these definitions stands a system for which the electoral results 8 Italy is divided in 20 Regions, 5 of which are ruled under Special Statutes and 20 by Ordinary Statutes. 2 were almost irrelevant to determine the ruling government color, with a dominant party, the Christian Democratic Party (DC), leading by itself for a certain period and from the very end of the seventies governing through a system of alliances with the Socialist Party (PS), the Republicans (PR), the Liberals (PL), and the Social Democrats (PSD), in the so-called Penta-Party coalition. From the very origin of the First Republic, the Communist Party (PC) was the main opponent party and, but for a few years between 1976 to 1979 (Government of National Solidarity), the PC was never part of the central government.9 However, the PC was more actively involved in leading regional governments, where it used to rule with and without the support of the PS. As a consequences, the color of regional governments, for instance, could change even during the same legislature period if the PS moved from an alliance with the DC to an agreement with the PC (see Tables in the Appendix for further details). The 1992 earthquake stroke a worn-out political system in a moment of economic distress, at the verge of which both the DC and the PC arrived after undergoing multiple internal crises. In fact, in 1991 the PC disbanded and two new parties collected its members: Democratic Party of the Left (PDS) and Communist Refoundation (RC).10 The reason of such choice was related more to the events shaking east European countries than to internal Italian changes. The heirs of the PC were left out of from the scandals and in the period immediately after the break they regained political support for that. As reaction to both the economic crisis and the scandal upheaval, the Penta-Party coalition (winners from 1992 national elections) sustaining technical governments until Italians were called to vote again in 1994 with a new electoral rule, through with the 75% of the seats in Parliament were assigned based on a majoritarian rule. A new political force came into play with a center right coalition lead by Silvio Berlusconi, who managed to be nominated head of the government for part of the new legislature. After internal disagreements to that coalition, a new technical government was established although it was mainly supported by the left wing parties. It was only with the new elections in 1996 that a political stability was gained again and a turnover between a right and a left coalition was established. Regional governments reached a new balance pretty much in the same period, since their elections are dated around that time, with exceptions due to Regions with Special Statutes (see Tables in the Appendix). Figure 1 summarizes the time line from the First to the Second Republic, focusing on the period analyzed in the empirical part. Figure 1 1985 → 1994 First Republic Proportional system − 1992 → 1996 Transition Period Technical governments − 1994 → 2005 Second Republic Majoritarian system 9 Even during these years, when Italian institutions feared the treat of the terrorist Red Brigades, the PC was not formally part of the central government but it rather supported it informally. 10 For further details on the Italian party system, see Bull and Newell (2005). 3 2.2 The Italian Constitutional Court The Italian Constitutional Court was established in 1955, although contemplated since 1948 by the Italian Constitution after WWII.11 There are fifteen judges appointed by three different political actors (President of the Republic, both Houses of Parliament, and judges) who appoint five judges each. All of them are selected among active or retired judges, professors of law, or lawyers with more than twenty years of professional experience, for nonrenewable terms of nine years. Till 1992 the quota system used to select the Justices by the Parliament was quite apparent and well consolidated/documented. After the 1996 national elections a similar balance has been reestablished. However the political chaos originated by the clean hands scandal provided a vacuum for the period between 1992 and 1994. The politicization of the Italian Constitutional Court has been studied by political scientists and legal economists [Guarnieri (2001); Breton and Fraschini (2003); Fiorino et. al. (2007); Pederzoli (2008); Padovano (2009); and Dalla Pellegrina and Garoupa (2012)]. 3 The Econometric Model 3.1 Model and Variables Definition To test our main research question, we start defining the political affiliation of the petitioner, the lawmaker, and the court for each analyzed decision of the Court. First, we construct two dummies named respectively Petitioner and Lawmaker. Petitioner takes the value of 1 when: 1) the petitioner is the State/National Government and the Central Government is ruled by the PentaParty till 1994 or it is ruled by the Right Wing Coalition after 1994, or 2) the petitioner is a Regional Government and the Regional Government is ruled by the PentaParty till the first regional election after the 1992 break or it is ruled by the Right Wing Coalition after the first regional election after the 1992 break. To assign the color and composition of the ruling Government we use the year of the court decision. Analogously, the Lawmaker dummy is defined, but for year taken to define the national or regional legislature coalitions which the year of the reviewed law enactment. The court political affiliation (Court) cannot be defined in terms of categorical variables, given we do not have the individual decisions. Therefore we opt for a continuous variable, that takes values between 0 and 1, since it represents a share. We are measuring the share of the Court aligned to the PentaParty from 1985 to 1993 and the share of the Court aligned to the Right Wing coalition from 1994 to 2005. In order to produce such measure, we count the number of aligned Justices out of the total number of Justices sitting in the Court for each decisions. At this stage, the number of the so-called neutral Justices is included in the denominator. Our measure allows us to weigh the marginal impact of a higher or lower incidence of a clear alignment, which in turns could have an effect also on the decisions of allegedly neutral Justices. We then define the share of the Court aligned to the petitioner’s party (ali petitioner) 11 The law that defines its procedural rules was approved in 1953 and the Court started working in 1956. 4 and the share of the Court opposed to the petitioner’s party (ali opp petitioner). Since we have already defined the petitioner’s party, ali petitioner is equal to the court political affiliation as described above, when the petitioner dummy takes the value of 1, and to (1Court), when Petitioner is zero. The reason is intuitive: if the petitioner is affiliated to the PentaParty (before 1994) or to the Right Wing party (after 1994) the part of the Court aligned to him/her is the share of Justices affiliated to the PentaParty (before 1994) or to the Right Wing party (after 1994). Whereas if the petitioner does not belong to the PentaParty or to the Right Wing, then it is the share of the Court not affiliated with the PentaParty or to the Right Wing, which is aligned to the petitioner. To define ali opp petitioner we take into account both the neutral Justices and that the Justices appointed under the First Republic still ruling after the break. The FR Justices will take some time to realign in the new Party system. Although it is unlike that they will be neutral, overall it is not possible to set the moment in which they will be associable to a new political affiliation. They previous affiliation, under the FR system, might not be conclusive in terms of SR choice since we know that, for instance, several politicians from the Christian Democrats party move in the Left Wing coalition, while others ended up in the Right Wing together with many belonging to the Socialist Party. Hence, we generate the share of the First Republic Justices (FRJugdes) and a share of the Neutral Justices (Neutral), as usual out of the number of Justices composing the Court at the decision level. ali opp petitioner is a continuous variable defined by the petitioner color. If the petitioner is aligned to the PentaParty or the Right Wing (Petitioner= 1) ali opp petitioner is the share of the Court not aligned to the PentaParty or the Right Wing including the neutral Justices (1-(Court+Neutral)) or including both the neutral Justices and the FR Justices share if the decision year is after 1994 (1-(Court+Neutral+FRJugdes)). When the petitioner is not aligned to the PentaParty or the Right Wing (Petitioner= 0), ali opp petitioner is equal to the share of the Court aligned to the PentaParty or the Right Wing coalition including the neutral Justices (Court+Neutral) or including both the neutral Justices and the FR Justices if the decision year is after 1994 (Court+Neutral+FRJugdes). We follow a similar approach to define the share of the Court aligned to the lawmaker’s party (ali lawmaker) and the share of the Court opposed to the lawmaker’s party (ali opp lawmaker), with the only difference being that we use the political affiliation of the lawmaker (Lawmaker). Once defined the main variables of interest, and set the dependent variable (Const) equal to a dummy equal to 1 if the Court declares the constitutionality of the reviewed law and 0 otherwise, we estimate the following model: Constit = γr + λt + θ1Ali petitionerit + θ2Ali lawmakerit + (1) θ3Ali opp petitionerit + θ3Ali opp lawmakerit + αPetitionerit + βLawmakerit + τCourtit + Zitω + Xitδ + εit 5 Where γr= Macro Areas Fixed Effects, λt= Year Fixed Effects, i= 1, 2...779 decisions, and t= 1985...2005. Z is vector of variables, which weight for the Justices pre-Court working background, and X is a vector of variables, which measure the court composition in terms of its electoral bodies. Hence, Z includes the share career judges of the Court (Career) and the share of law professors/legal scholars (Law), whereas X comprehends the proportion of the Court appointed by both Houses of the Parliament (Parliament), by the President of the Republic (President), and by the Magistracy (Magistracy). Controlling for the petitioner, the lawmaker, and the court political alignment, the fixed effects, X , and Z , a marginal increase in the alignment of the Court with the petitioner should increase the probability of a declaration of the unconstitutionality of the law. A similar effect is expected to be driven by a marginal increase in the share of the court opposed to the lawmaker. A reverse effect is expected when there is an increase in the proportion of the Court aligned to the lawmaker or opposed to the petitioner (see Table 1 for a summary of the expected effects). Basically, we are assuming that moving from the consensual to the majoritarian democracy the described effects turn out to be more significant. In order to test for this expectation, we run model 1 on 4 periods of interest: the First Republic period (1985- 1994), the First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), the Second Republic period (1994-2005), and the Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). Table 1 about here 3.2 Robustness Checks As robustness checks, we verify the consistency of our results under the following scenarios: 1. When there is a mixed political affiliation; (a) For regional laws, when the lawmakers belong to different parties; (b) For national laws, when the petitioners belong to different parties; 2. When there is alignment between the lawmaker and the petitioner; 3. The alignments concern the rapporteur and the president of the Court; 4. When the transition period is considered. Once the legislator’ level comes into play, we construct a dummy variable equal to 1 if the reviewed law is regional and 0 if it is national (reg law). Distinguishing between national and regional legislations allows to check: 1) when the State is the petitioner against laws promulgated by Regions which have different political colors, and 2) when Regions with different political affiliations pool together as petitioners against a National Law. Both in the first and in the second case we could expect that the Court’s decisions deal with a lower political biased issue and therefore we might want to check if our results are consistent once these decisions are dropped by the considered sample. 6 In addition to the mixed alignment checks, we construct a dummy to control for those decisions for which the petitioner has the same affiliation of the lawmaker, which can be quite the case during the First Republic (see Table 5). We consider the case in which there is an alignment between the petitioner and the decision Rapporteur (ali pet rapporteur) and the petitioner and the President of the Court (ali pet president), as well as the alignment between the lawmaker and the decision Rapporteur (ali law rapporteur) and the petitioner and the President of the Court (ali law president). Finally, we check model 1 only on the transition period decisions (from 1992 to 1996). 4 Descriptives Statistics and Results 4.1 Data We collected the 779 main reviews (ricorsi in via principale) ruled by the SC from 1985 to 2005. When the multiple issues decided in the same sentence are considered we end up with 926 issues. Finally, we count for the fact that constitutional reviews might be filed by more than one Region and that the Government could appeal to the SC against the laws approved by different Regions although related to the same topic. This is why, as shown in Table 2, once the regional level is included, we have a final dataset of 1,371 decisions. These decisions concerned laws or legislative decrees both at the national and at the regional (or provincial) level enacted from 1976 to 2005 as shown in Table 3. Tables 2 and 3 about here In Table 4 we report the composition of the Court in a dynamic setting, moving from the First to the Second Republic. During the First Republic, it is apparent the overwhelming majority of the PentaParty components of the Court, with a small opposition made by those Justices elected among the Communist Party adherents. The heritage of the First Republic is still an important element in the years after the break, as detected but the percentage of FR Justices.12 As a matter of fact, a new Court majority (8 Justices out of 15) appointed under the new party system has been established only in 1997, given that 2 Justices were appointed in 1995, 5 in 1996, and 1 in 1997. A higher incidence of Justices affiliated to the Left Wing coalition start to become apparent after 1996. Table 4 about here Table 5 presents descriptives statistics for the four periods of interest as previously defined. Table 5 about here 12 There are 7 Justices nominated in the neighbor of the party system collapse: 1 in 1990 (Granata), 3 in 1991 (Guizzi, Mirabelli, and Vassalli), 1 in 1992 (Santuosso), and 2 in 1993 (Ruperto and Vari). 7 4.2 Results We present results for model 1 in the four periods first excluding the shares of the court opposed to the petitioner and the lawmaker (Table 6) and then including them (Table 7). The very first evidence show an effect on the Court political partisanship related to the move from the consensual to a majoritarjan democracy. Although this effect is not robust to the full estimation of model 1. Tables 6 and 7 about here When the model is tested on sub-sets of decisions, grouped according to the national or regional nature of the reviewed laws, it is apparent that the first effect detected in Table 6 is reaffirmed, robust to the full specification, only for those decisions dealing with national legislation (see Table 9). Tables 8 and 9 about here Our results are robust to the the checks listed in subsection 3.2. In particular, there are only 3 cases13 in which the State filed for the review of regional laws (lawmaker) when Regions have different political colors, and as such they did not change the results. However, we count 128 decisions for which Regions of different political colors (petitioner) filed for the review of State laws. Even when those are dropped, the results of model 1 stand unchanged. The same results are confirmed even when controlling for ali pet rapporteur, ali law rapporteur, ali pet president, and ali law president. Results of testing model 1 on the transition period do not address any significant behaviors during that period. 5 Conclusive Remarks Our paper addresses political partisanship in constitutional review, in particular, when moving from a consensual to a majoritarian democracy (concepts that rely fundamentally on different electoral rules). We study how these distinctions affect and influence judicial review. In particular, we use a structural break in the Italian party system to evaluate changes in the pattern of political bias exhibited by the constitutional judges. Our preliminary results provide significant support against a formalist interpretation of judicial behavior. They also seem to indicate more alignment in a majoritarian rather than in a consensual model. 13 Sentences n.119/1985; 162/2004; and 62/2005. 8 References Alarie, Benjamin and Andrew J. Green (2008,) Should They All Just Get Along? Judicial Ideology, Collegiality, and Appointments to the Supreme Court of Canada, University of New Brunswick Law Journal 53, 73-91. Amaral Garcia, Sofia, Nuno Garoupa and Veronica Grembi (2009), Judicial Independence and Party Politics in the Kelsenian Constitutional Courts: the Case of Portugal, Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 6, 383. Brenner, Saul and Harold J. Spaeth (1988), Ideological Position as a Variable in the Authoring of Dissenting Opinions on the Warren and Burger Courts, American Politics Quarterly 16, 317-28. Breton, A. and A. Fraschini (2003), The Independence of the Italian Constitutional Court, Constitutional Political Economy 14, 319. Bull, Martin J. and James L. Newell (2005), Italian Politics. Adjustment Under Duress, Cambridge Polity Press. Chavez, Rebecca Bill (2004), The Rule of Law in Nascent Democracies: Judicial Politics in Argentina, Palo Alto: Stanford University Press. Dalla Pellegrina, Lucia and Nuno Garoupa (2012), Choosing between the Government and the Regions: An Empirical Analysis of the Italian Constitutional Court Decisions, mimeograph on file with the authors. Dorff, Robert H. and Saul Brenner (1992), Conformity Voting on the United States Supreme Court, Journal of Politics 54, 762-75. Epstein, Lee and Jack Knight (1998), The Choices Justices Make, Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Inc. Epstein, Lee, Jeffrey A. Segal and Harold J. Spaeth (2001), The Norm of Consensus on the U.S. Supreme Court, American Journal of Political Science 45, 362-77. Escresa Gulliermo Laarni and Nuno Garoupa (2012), Judicial Politics in Unstable Democracies: The Case of the Philippine Supreme Court, 1986-2010, mimeograph in file with authors. Fiorino, Nadia, Fabio Padovano and Grazia Sgarra (2007), The Determinants of Judicial Independence: Evidence from the Italian Constitutional Court (1956-2002), Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 163, 683. 9 Franck, Raphael (2009), Judicial Independence under a Divided Polity: A Study of the Rulings of the French Constitutional Court, 1959-2006, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 25, 262-84. Franck, Raphael (2010) Judicial Independence and the Validity of Controverted Elections, American Law and Economics Review 12, 394-422. Garoupa, Nuno, Fernando Gomez and Veronica Grembi (2013), Judging Under Political Pressure: An Empirical Analysis of Constitutional Review Voting in the Spanish Constitutional Court, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, forthcoming. Garoupa, Nuno, Veronica Grembi and Shirley Lin (2011), Explaining Constitutional Review in New Democracies: The Case of Taiwan, 20 Pacific Rim Law and Policy Journal 1-40. Gely, Rafael and Pablo T. Spiller (1990), A Rational Choice Theory of Supreme Court Statutory Decisions with Applications to the State Farm and Grove City Cases, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 6, 263-300. George, Tracey E. and Lee Epstein (1992), On the Nature of Supreme Court Decision Making, American Political Science Review 86, 323-37. Ginsburg, Tom (2003), Judicial Review in New Democracies: Constitutional Courts in Asian Cases, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Green, Andrew J. and Benjamin Alarie (2009), Policy Preference Change and Appointments to the Supreme Court of Canada, Osgoode Hall Law Journal 47, 1-46. Guarnieri, Carlo (1997), The Judiciary in the Italian Political Crisis, West European Politics 20, 157. Guarnieri, Carlo (2001), Judicial Independence in Latin Countries of Western Europe, in Peter H. Russell and David M. O’Brien (eds.) Judicial Independence in the Age of Democracy. Critical Perspectives From around the World, 111-130. Guarnieri, Carlo (2003), Giustizia e politica. I nodi della Seconda Repubblica, XXXX. Guarnieri, Carlo (2006), Il Sistema Politico Italiano, Bologna, Il Mulino. Hansford, Thomas G. and James F. Springgs II (2006), The Politics of Precedent on the US Supreme Court, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Helmke, Gretchen (2004), Courts under Constraints: Judges, Generals, and Presidents in Argentina, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hilbink, Lisa (2007), Judges beyond Politics in Democracy and Dictatorship: Lessons from Chile. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 10 Iaryczower, Matias, Pablo T. Spiller and Mariano Tommasi (2002), Judicial Independence in Unstable Environments, Argentina 1935-1998, American Journal of Political Science 46, 699-716. Iaryczower, Matias, Pablo T. Spiller and Mariano Tommasi (2006), Judicial Lobbying: The Politics of Labor Law Constitutional Interpretation, American Political Science Review 100, 1-13. Kapiszewski, Diana and Matthew M. Taylor (2008), Doing Courts Justice? Studying Judicial Politics in Latin America, Perspectives in Politics 64, 741-67. Lax, Jeffrey R. and Charles M. Cameron (2007), Bargaining and Opinion Assignment on the US Supreme Court, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 23, 276-302. Lijphart, Arend (1999), Patterns to Democracy, New Haven, Yale University Press. Lizzeri, A. and N. Persico (2001), The Provision of Public Goods under Alternative Electoral Incentives, American Economic Review 91, 225-239. Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., and M. Rostagno (2002), Electoral Systems and Public Spending, Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 609-657. Myerson, R. B. (1993), Effectiveness of the Electoral Systems for Reducing Government Corruption: A Game-Theoretic Analysis, Games and Economic Behavior 5, 118-132. Padovano, Fabio (2009), The Time-Varying Independence of Italian Peak Judicial Institutions, Constitutional Political Economy 20, 239. Pasquino, Pasquale (1998), Constitutional Adjudication and Democracy. Comparative Perspectives: USA, France, Italy, Ratio Juris 1, 38. Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (1999), The Size and Scope of Government: Comparative Politics with Rational Politicians, European Economic Review 43, 699-735. Persson, T. and G. Tabellini (2000), Political Economics, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Pederzoli, Patrizia (2008), La Corte Costituzionale, Bologna: Il Mulino. Ramseyer, J. Mark and Eric B. Rasmusen (2003), Measuring Judicial Independence: The Political Economy of Judging in Japan, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Robertson, David (2010), The Judge as Political Theorist, Princeton: Princeton University Press. Santoni, Michele and Francesco Zucchini (2003), Legislative Output and the Constitutional Court in Italy, Constitutional Political Economy 17, 165. 11 Segal, Jeffrey A. and A. D. Cover (1989), Ideological Values and the Votes of US Supreme Court Justices, American Political Science Review 83, 557-65. Segal, Jeffrey A. and Harold J. Spaeth (2002), The Supreme Court and the Attitudinal Model Revisited. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Spiller, Pablo T. and Rafael Gely (2007), Strategic Judicial Decision Making, NBER Working Paper 13321. Tate, C. Neal and Panu Sittiwong (1989), Decision Making in the Canadian Supreme Court: Extending the Personal Attributes Model Across Nations, Journal of Politics 51, 900-16. Vanberg, Georg (2005), The Politics of Constitutional Review in Germany, Cambridge University Press. Volcansek, Mary L. (2000), Constitutional Politics in Italy, Palgrave Macmillan Press. 12 Tables Table 1: Model Previsions Dependent Ali petitioner Ali lawmaker Ali opp petitioner Ali opp lawmaker Variable (if it increases) (if it increases) (if it increases) (if it increases) Const 1 ↓ ↓ 0 ↑ ↑ 13 Table 2: Decisions According to the Decision Year Year Decisions Decided Per Region Issues Issues 1985 19 22 35 1986 16 19 35 1987 29 35 59 1988 106 121 148 1989 31 36 57 1990 46 53 70 1991 26 38 68 1992 32 45 84 1993 30 39 63 1994 44 58 77 1995 42 49 66 1996 25 29 33 1997 21 21 25 1998 11 14 23 1999 24 25 26 2000 26 31 37 2001 26 33 41 2002 12 14 30 2003 48 57 93 2004 80 87 168 2005 85 100 133 Total 779 926 1,371 14 Table 3: Decisions According to the Reviewed Law Year Year Decisions Decided Issues Per Region Issues Tot. NL RL Tot. NL RL Tot. NL RL 1976 6 0 6 8 0 8 9 0 9 1977 12 3 9 13 3 10 14 3 11 1978 13 7 6 16 9 7 19 12 7 1979 6 0 6 7 0 7 7 0 7 1980 10 3 7 11 3 8 14 6 8 1981 24 13 11 28 15 13 41 28 23 1982 20 11 9 21 12 9 27 18 9 1983 11 4 7 13 6 7 19 12 7 1984 13 11 2 16 14 2 36 34 2 1985 17 10 7 19 12 7 34 25 9 1986 20 9 11 23 10 13 29 16 13 1987 15 6 9 18 8 10 25 15 10 1988 26 7 19 30 9 21 36 15 21 1989 41 17 24 50 21 29 81 52 29 1990 34 13 21 40 18 22 58 36 22 1991 34 25 9 49 36 13 94 81 13 1992 33 21 12 46 29 17 73 56 17 1993 34 17 17 45 23 22 64 42 22 1994 34 12 22 44 16 28 62 34 28 1995 40 8 32 43 9 34 48 14 34 1996 35 13 22 39 16 23 52 26 26 1997 33 9 24 41 16 25 50 24 26 1998 27 14 13 30 17 13 37 24 13 1999 15 12 3 18 15 3 22 19 3 2000 10 5 5 13 6 7 22 15 7 2001 22 14 8 23 15 8 39 31 8 2002 75 33 42 84 36 48 133 84 49 2003 66 39 27 73 44 29 127 88 39 2004 48 25 23 59 34 25 94 69 25 2005 3 0 3 4 0 4 5 0 5 Total 777* 924* 1,371 Notes: *= the total numbers differ from the issues reviewed per year since two decisions concern regional laws promulgated in different years. They count in the regional level analysis. Tot.= Total; NL= National Laws; RL= Regional Laws. 15 Table 4: Court Composition Year %PP %Opponent % Neutral %FR %Right %Left 1985 0.71 0.07 0.21 . . . 1986 0.70 0.09 0.21 . . . 1987 0.66 0.15 0.19 . . . 1988 0.66 0.13 0.21 . . . 1989 0.66 0.13 0.20 . . . 1990 0.66 0.14 0.20 . . . 1991 0.54 0.16 0.30 . . . 1992 0.61 0.13 0.26 . . . 1993 0.64 0.15 0.21 . . . 1994 0.09 0.02 0.26 0.63 0.00 0.00 1995 . . 0.32 0.58 0.00 0.10 1996 . . 0.30 0.46 0.05 0.19 1997 . . 0.30 0.23 0.09 0.38 1998 . . 0.28 0.22 0.12 0.38 1999 . . 0.26 0.21 0.14 0.40 2000 . . 0.20 0.14 0.14 0.52 2001 . . 0.20 0.00 0.16 0.62 2002 . . 0.07 0.00 0.20 0.73 2003 . . 0.00 0.00 0.29 0.71 2004 . . 0.00 0.00 0.29 0.71 2005 . . 0.00 0.00 0.33 0.67 Notes: %PP= Share of the PentaParty Judges; %Opponent= Share of Communist Judges; %Neutral= Share of Neutral Judges; %FR= Share of Judges appointed during the First Republic; %Right= Share of Right Wing Judges; %Left= Share of Left Wing Judges. 16 Table 5: Descriptives for the 4 periods FR FR SR SR no transition no transition Ali petitioner 0.56 0.56 0.57 0.57 (0.14) (0.14) (0.33) (0.27) Ali lawmaker 0.60 0.60 0.43 0.50 (0.11) (0.11) (0.33) (0.28) Ali opp petitioner 0.36 0.35 0.51 0.50 (0.34) (0.34) (0.27) (0.19) Ali opp lawmaker 0.21 0.21 0.33 0.38 (0.23) (0.23) (0.24) (0.20) Petitioner 0.69 0.70 0.38 0.37 (0.46) (0.46) (0.49) (0.48) Lawmaker 0.89 0.89 0.63 0.59 (0.31) (0.31) (0.49) (0.48) Court 0.64 0.64 0.19 0.24 (0.06) (0.06) (0.13) (0.10) Neutral 0.22 0.22 0.12 0.08 (0.05) (0.05) (0.14) (0.12) Career 0.40 0.41 0.35 0.33 (0.04) (0.04) (0.06) (0.06) Law 0.47 0.47 0.60 0.62 (0.05) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06) Parliament 0.25 0.25 0.27 0.29 (0.05) (0.05) (0.09) (0.07) President 0.34 0.34 0.36 0.36 (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) (0.05) Magistracy 0.40 0.40 0.35 0.33 (0.06) (0.05) (0.06) (0.06) Petitioner=Lawmaker 0.59 0.59 0.31 0.30 (0.49) (0.49) (0.46) (0.46) Regional Law 0.33 0.34 0.38 0.36 (0.47) (0.47) (0.49) (0.48) Notes: Standard Deviations in brackets. FR= First Republic period (1985-1994), FR no transition= First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), SR= Second Republic period (1994-2005), and SR no transition= Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). 17 Table 6: Results: Model VARIABLES FR FR SR SR no transition no transition ali petitioner -0.04 -0.05 -0.33 -0.68** (-0.13) (-0.18) (-1.57) (-2.09) ali lawmaker 0.23 0.86 -0.03 -0.37 (0.28) (0.95) (-0.13) (-1.02) Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Macro Area FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 631 555 566 446 Pseudo Log-Likelihood -375.69 -327.83 -351.49 -270.55 Notes: Declaration of constitutionality is the dependent variable. Control variables are Petitioner, Lawmaker, Court, Career, Parliament, and President. Marginal effects reported. FR= First Republic period (1985-1994), FR no transition= First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), SR= Second Republic period (1994-2005), and SR no transition= Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). Robust zstatistics clustered at the case level in brackets. Significance at the 10% level is represented by *, at the 5% level by **, and at the 1% level by ***. 18 Table 7: Results: Model with Opponents VARIABLES FR FR SR SR no transition no transition ali petitioner -0.30 -0.41 -0.34 -0.52 (-0.83) (-1.00) (-0.89) (-1.37) ali lawmaker 0.18 0.62 -0.10 -0.31 (0.19) (0.60) (-0.22) (-0.58) ali opp petitioner -1.12 -1.27 -0.01 -0.22 (-1.57) (-1.51) (-0.04) (-0.84) ali opp lawmaker -0.50 -0.77 0.04 -0.04 (-0.41) (-0.56) (0.19) (-0.17) Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Macro Area FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 631 555 566 446 Pseudo Log-Likelihood -374.59 -326.69 -351.46 -270.09 Notes: Declaration of constitutionality is the dependent variable. Control variables are Petitioner, Lawmaker, Court, Career, Parliament, and President. Marginal effects reported. FR= First Republic period (1985-1994), FR no transition= First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), SR= Second Republic period (1994-2005), and SR no transition= Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). Robust zstatistics clustered at the case level in brackets. Significance at the 10% level is represented by *, at the 5% level by **, and at the 1% level by ***. 19 Table 8: Results: Only Regional Laws VARIABLES FR FR SR SR no transition no transition ali petitioner -0.04 -0.11 -0.40 -0.55 (-0.15) (-0.31) (-0.77) (-1.06) ali lawmaker -0.83 -1.23 -0.05 0.32 (-0.71) (-0.68) (-0.07) (0.36) ali opp petitioner -0.05 -0.18 0.23 0.09 (-0.09) (-0.25) (1.08) (0.25) ali opp lawmaker -1.02 -1.93 -0.25 -0.06 (-0.46) (-0.70) (-0.77) (-0.18) Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Macro Area FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 425 364 338 279 Pseudo Log-Likelihood -243.03 -207.84 -194.91 -152.79 Notes: Declaration of constitutionality is the dependent variable. Control variables are Petitioner, Lawmaker, Court, Career, Parliament, and President. Marginal effects reported. FR= First Republic period (1985-1994), FR no transition= First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), SR= Second Republic period (1994-2005), and SR no transition= Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). Robust zstatistics clustered at the case level in brackets. Significance at the 10% level is represented by *, at the 5% level by **, and at the 1% level by ***. 20 Table 9: Results: Only National Laws VARIABLES FR FR SR SR no transition no transition ali petitioner 0.34 -0.43 -2.19** -2.63** (0.18) (-0.21) (-2.09) (-2.31) ali lawmaker 0.78 1.41 1.09 0.41 (0.65) (1.16) (1.23) (0.44) ali opp petitioner -0.27 -0.94 -0.18 -0.10 (-0.10) (-0.35) (-0.22) (-0.12) ali opp lawmaker -1.29 -1.07 -0.44 -0.56 (-0.68) (-0.59) (-1.08) (-1.37) Control Variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Macro Area FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 206 188 226 165 Pseudo Log-Likelihood -123.66 -111.06 -127.67 -89.14 Notes: Declaration of constitutionality is the dependent variable. Control variables are Petitioner, Lawmaker, Court, Career, Parliament, and President. Marginal effects reported. FR= First Republic period (1985-1994), FR no transition= First Republic without the transition period (1985-1992), SR= Second Republic period (1994-2005), and SR no transition= Second Republic without the transition period (1996-2005). Robust zstatistics clustered at the case level in brackets. Significance at the 10% level is represented by *, at the 5% level by **, and at the 1% level by ***. 21 Appendix Table A1: National Elections Date Winning Coalition Government Coalition June 20, 1976 NS NS June 3, 1979 PP PP June 26, 1983 PP PP June 14, 1987 PP PP April 4, 1992 PP June 28, 1992 to Amato April 28, 1993 April 28, 1993 to Ciampi May 10, 1994 March 27, 1994 R May 10, 1994 to Berlusconi January 17, 1995 January 17, 1995 to Dini May 17, 1996 L April 21, 1996 L L May 13, 2001 R R Notes: PP= PentaParty Coalition; L=Left Wing Coalition; R= Right Wing Coalition. Amato, Ciampi, and Dini Governments are regarded as technocrats’ government. However, they were supported by specific political coalitions. NS= National Solidarity (Solidarieta’ Nazionale). From 1976 to 1979 a broad coalition was at the national government, which included an informal participation also of the Communist Party. A broader national government coalition was pushed by the Seventies Red Brigate terrostic treat. Source: Italian Ministry of the Interior. 22 Table A2: Regional Elections: Ordinary Statute Regions Regions 1975- 1980- 1985- 1990- 1995- 2000- 2005- 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Abruzzo PP PP PP PP L R L Basilicata PP PP PP PP L L L Calabria PP PP PP PP R R L Campania PP PP PP PP R L L Emilia Romagna NPP NPP NPP NPP L L L Lazio NPP NPP/PP PP PP L R L Liguria NPP PP PP PP L R L Lombardia PP PP PP PP R R R Marche PP/NPP NPP NPP NPP L L R Molise PP PP PP PP L R* R* Piemonte PP PP PP NPP L L R Puglia PP PP PP PP R R L Toscana NPP NPP NPP NPP L L L Umbria NPP NPP NPP NPP L L L Veneto PP PP PP PP R R R Notes: PP= PentaParty Coalition; NPP= No PentaParty Coalition, which includes the Communist Party; L=Left Wing Coalition; R= Right Wing Coalition. In some cases the presence of in the ruling coalition of the Communist Party depends on the alliances policy of the Socialist Party: this is why we can have that during a same legislature there is shift from NPP to PP or viceversa. R∗=Elections in Molise were held in 2001 and 2006 rather than 2000 and 2005. The election dates were for all on: June 15, 1975; June 8, 1980; May 12, 1985; May 6, 1990; April 23, 1995; April 16, 2000. Source: Italian Ministry of the Interior. 23 Table A3: Regional Elections: Special Statute Regions Regions 1973- 1978- 1983- 1988- 1993- 1998- 2003- 1978- 1983 1988 1993 1998 2003 2006 Friuli Venezia Giulia PP PP PP PP R R L Valle d’Aosta PP AUT AUT AUT AUT AUT AUT Trentino Alto Adige AUT AUT AUT AUT L L L Bolzano AUT AUT AUT AUT L L L Trento PP PP PP PP L L L 1974- 1979- 1984- 1989- 1994- 1999- 2004- 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 Sardegna PP PP PP PP R R L 1976- 1981- 1986- 1991- 1996- 2001 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 Sicilia PP PP PP PP R R Notes: PP= PentaParty Coalition; L=Left Wing Coalition; R= Right Wing Coalition; AUT=Regional Parties connected to territorial and linguistic concerns. In Friuli Venezia Giulia and Valle D’Aosta elections took place on June 25, 1978; June 26, 1983; June 26, 1988; June 6, 1993; May 31, 1998, and June 8, 2003. In Trentino Alto Adige elections took place on November 11, 1978; November 20, 1983; November 20, 1988; November 21, 1993, November 22, 1998; and October 26, 2003. Bolzano and Trento are the two autonomous provinces in Trentino Alto Adige. Source: Italian Ministry of the Interior. 24 Table A4: Regional Governments during the National Transition Period Regions 1992 1993 1994 1995 Abruzzo PP PP L L Basilicata PP PP PP PP Calabria PP PP L L/R Campania PP PP PP PP Emilia Romagna NPP NPP NPP NPP Lazio NPP NPP/PP PP PP Liguria NPP PP PP/L L Lombardia PP PP L R Marche PP/NPP NPP NPP NPP Molise PP PP PP PP Piemonte PP PP PP/L L/L Puglia PP PP PP PP Toscana NPP NPP NPP NPP Umbria NPP NPP NPP NPP Veneto PP PP/L L/R R Friuli Venezia Giulia PP PP/R L/R L* Valle d’Aosta AUT AUT AUT AUT Trentino Alto Adige AUT L L L Bolzano AUT L L L Trento PP PP/L L L Sardegna PP PP PP/R R Sicilia PP/NPP NPP NPP NPP Notes: PP= PentaParty Coalition; NPP= No PentaParty Coalition, which includes the Communist Party; L=Left Wing Coalition; R= Right Wing Coalition; AUT= Autonomous Parties. Source: Italian Ministry of the Interior and regional websites. *= till 1998. 25